|
When
Bernanke gave this speech in November 2002, there really was monetary deflation
in the U.S., as shown by the dollar hovering around $260/oz. of gold, the
highest dollar value in about 24 years. This was showing up in the economy,
and a number of people -- including those I worked with -- were yapping at
Greenspan to do something about it. Greenspan did, taking the Fed's target
rate to 1%.
It
seems to me that Bernanke, then a FOMC member, sensed that his own
inflationist ideas were enjoying a moment of political acceptance, and jumped
on that bandwagon. However, those "anti-deflation" efforts were
specifically for the situation of that time. Bernanke, like most Keynesian
inflationists, is something of a one-trick pony. Bernanke's stopped clock was
right in 2002, but it is wholly wrong today. Greenspan -- the gold-watcher --
would never have been doing this stuff if he was still in office. But, that's
what he was trying to say with his "Age of Turbulence", no?
Let's
take a look at Bernanke's speech in detail. I suspect that he is the sort
that applies this sort of thinking to basically everything that comes at him.
My comments are in RED.
Bernanke's 2002 speech
Deflation:
Making Sure "It" Doesn't Happen Here
Since World War II, inflation--the apparently inexorable rise in the prices
of goods and services--has been the bane of central bankers. Economists of
various stripes have argued that inflation is the inevitable result of (pick
your favorite) the abandonment of metallic monetary standards, a lack of
fiscal discipline, shocks to the price of oil and other commodities,
struggles over the distribution of income, excessive money creation,
self-confirming inflation expectations, an "inflation bias" in the
policies of central banks, and still others. [NWE:
Bernanke doesn't know what causes inflation.] Despite widespread
"inflation pessimism," however, during the 1980s and 1990s most
industrial-country central banks were able to cage, if not entirely tame, the
inflation dragon. Although a number of factors converged to make this happy
outcome possible, an essential element was the heightened understanding by
central bankers and, equally as important, by political leaders and the
public at large of the very high costs of allowing the economy to stray too
far from price stability.
With
inflation rates now quite low in the United States, however, some have
expressed concern that we may soon face a new problem--the danger of
deflation, or falling prices. That this concern is not purely hypothetical is
brought home to us whenever we read newspaper reports about Japan, where what
seems to be a relatively moderate deflation--a decline in consumer prices of
about 1 percent per year--has been associated with years of painfully slow
growth, rising joblessness, and apparently intractable financial problems in
the banking and corporate sectors. While it is difficult to sort out cause
from effect, the consensus view is that deflation has been an important
negative factor in the Japanese slump.
NWE: Bernanke doesn't know what caused "deflation" in
Japan. It was monetary!
So, is
deflation a threat to the economic health of the United States? Not to leave
you in suspense, I believe that the chance of significant deflation in the
United States in the foreseeable future is extremely small, for two principal
reasons. [NWE: The U.S. was already in deflation at
that time -- as Greenspan understood.] The first is the resilience and
structural stability of the U.S. economy itself. Over the years, the U.S.
economy has shown a remarkable ability to absorb shocks of all kinds, to
recover, and to continue to grow. Flexible and efficient markets for labor
and capital, an entrepreneurial tradition, and a general willingness to
tolerate and even embrace technological and economic change all contribute to
this resiliency. A particularly important protective factor in the current
environment is the strength of our financial system: Despite the adverse
shocks of the past year, our banking system remains healthy and
well-regulated, and firm and household balance sheets are for the most part
in good shape. Also helpful is that inflation has recently been not only low
but quite stable, with one result being that inflation expectations seem well
anchored. For example, according to the University of Michigan survey that
underlies the index of consumer sentiment, the median expected rate of
inflation during the next five to ten years among those interviewed was 2.9
percent in October 2002, as compared with 2.7 percent a year earlier and 3.0
percent two years earlier--a stable record indeed.
NWE: Bernanke doesn't know what prevents deflation.
The
second bulwark against deflation in the United States, and the one that will
be the focus of my remarks today, is the Federal Reserve System itself. The
Congress has given the Fed the responsibility of preserving price stability
(among other objectives), which most definitely implies avoiding deflation as
well as inflation. I am confident that the Fed would take whatever means
necessary to prevent significant deflation in the United States and,
moreover, that the U.S. central bank, in cooperation with other parts of the
government as needed, has sufficient policy instruments to ensure that any
deflation that might occur would be both mild and brief.
Of
course, we must take care lest confidence become over-confidence.
Deflationary episodes are rare, and generalization about them is difficult.
Indeed, a recent Federal Reserve study of the Japanese experience concluded
that the deflation there was almost entirely unexpected, by both foreign and
Japanese observers alike (Ahearne et al., 2002). So, having said that
deflation in the United States is highly unlikely, I would be imprudent to
rule out the possibility altogether. Accordingly, I want to turn to a further
exploration of the causes of deflation, its economic effects, and the policy
instruments that can be deployed against it. Before going further I should
say that my comments today reflect my own views only and are not necessarily
those of my colleagues on the Board of Governors or the Federal Open Market
Committee.
Deflation:
Its Causes and Effects
Deflation
is defined as a general decline in prices, with emphasis on the word
"general." [NWE: Total lack of awareness of
monetary factors.] At any given time, especially in a low-inflation
economy like that of our recent experience, prices of some goods and services
will be falling. Price declines in a specific sector may occur because
productivity is rising and costs are falling more quickly in that sector than
elsewhere or because the demand for the output of that sector is weak
relative to the demand for other goods and services. Sector-specific price
declines, uncomfortable as they may be for producers in that sector, are
generally not a problem for the economy as a whole and do not constitute
deflation. Deflation per se occurs only when price declines are so widespread
that broad-based indexes of prices, such as the consumer price index,
register ongoing declines.
The
sources of deflation are not a mystery. Deflation is in almost all cases a
side effect of a collapse of aggregate demand--a drop in spending so severe
that producers must cut prices on an ongoing basis in order to find buyers.1 [NWE: In 1987, 1988 and 1989, the peak of the Japanese
"bubble", the CPI was around -2.0% when adjusting for the
introduction of a consumption tax. Bernanke is really talking about the
falling prices from economic contraction.] Likewise, the economic
effects of a deflationary episode, for the most part, are similar to those of
any other sharp decline in aggregate spending--namely, recession, rising
unemployment, and financial stress.
However,
a deflationary recession may differ in one respect from "normal" recessions
in which the inflation rate is at least modestly positive: Deflation of
sufficient magnitude may result in the nominal interest rate declining to
zero or very close to zero.2 Once the nominal interest rate is at zero, no
further downward adjustment in the rate can occur, since lenders generally
will not accept a negative nominal interest rate when it is possible instead
to hold cash. At this point, the nominal interest rate is said to have hit
the "zero bound."
Deflation
great enough to bring the nominal interest rate close to zero poses special
problems for the economy and for policy. First, when the nominal interest
rate has been reduced to zero, the real interest rate paid by borrowers
equals the expected rate of deflation, however large that may be.3 To take
what might seem like an extreme example (though in fact it occurred in the
United States in the early 1930s), suppose that deflation is proceeding at a
clip of 10 percent per year. Then someone who borrows for a year at a nominal
interest rate of zero actually faces a 10 percent real cost of funds, as the
loan must be repaid in dollars whose purchasing power is 10 percent greater
than that of the dollars borrowed originally. In a period of sufficiently
severe deflation, the real cost of borrowing becomes prohibitive. Capital
investment, purchases of new homes, and other types of spending decline
accordingly, worsening the economic downturn.
NWE: Remember I told you these guys cling to the notion of
"real interest rates"? A 4% interest rate with a gold standard --
like the U.S. had in 1932 -- is a 4% "real" interest rate. This is
all just an elaborate justification to jam the economy with money when it is
struggling.
Although
deflation and the zero bound on nominal interest rates create a significant
problem for those seeking to borrow, they impose an even greater burden on
households and firms that had accumulated substantial debt before the onset
of the deflation. This burden arises because, even if debtors are able to
refinance their existing obligations at low nominal interest rates, with
prices falling they must still repay the principal in dollars of increasing
(perhaps rapidly increasing) real value. When William Jennings Bryan made his
famous "cross of gold" speech in his 1896 presidential campaign, he
was speaking on behalf of heavily mortgaged farmers whose debt burdens were
growing ever larger in real terms, the result of a sustained deflation that
followed America's post-Civil-War return to the gold standard.4 [NWE: Oddly enough, Bernanke identifies a real, monetary
deflation. During the 1870s, the value of the dollar rose considerably to
correct for the "greenback" inflation of the Civil War 1860-1865.] The
financial distress of debtors can, in turn, increase the fragility of the
nation's financial system--for example, by leading to a rapid increase in the
share of bank loans that are delinquent or in default. Japan in recent years
has certainly faced the problem of "debt-deflation"--the
deflation-induced, ever-increasing real value of debts. [NWE: Despite citing the 1870s example, Bernanke
apparently doesn't realize that the EXACT same thing happened in Japan in the
1990s except about 2x worse! Ugh!] Closer to home, massive financial
problems, including defaults, bankruptcies, and bank failures, were endemic
in America's worst encounter with deflation, in the years 1930-33--a period
in which (as I mentioned) the U.S. price level fell about 10 percent per
year.
Beyond
its adverse effects in financial markets and on borrowers, the zero bound on
the nominal interest rate raises another concern--the limitation that it
places on conventional monetary policy. Under normal conditions, the Fed and
most other central banks implement policy by setting a target for a
short-term interest rate--the overnight federal funds rate in the United
States--and enforcing that target by buying and selling securities in open
capital markets. When the short-term interest rate hits zero, the central
bank can no longer ease policy by lowering its usual interest-rate target.5
Because
central banks conventionally conduct monetary policy by manipulating the
short-term nominal interest rate, some observers have concluded that when
that key rate stands at or near zero, the central bank has "run out of
ammunition"--that is, it no longer has the power to expand aggregate
demand and hence economic activity. It is true that once the policy rate has
been driven down to zero, a central bank can no longer use its traditional
means of stimulating aggregate demand and thus will be operating in less
familiar territory. The central bank's inability to use its traditional
methods may complicate the policymaking process and introduce uncertainty in
the size and timing of the economy's response to policy actions. Hence I
agree that the situation is one to be avoided if possible.
However,
a principal message of my talk today is that a central bank whose accustomed
policy rate has been forced down to zero has most definitely not run out of
ammunition. As I will discuss, a central bank, either alone or in cooperation
with other parts of the government, retains considerable power to expand
aggregate demand and economic activity even when its accustomed policy rate
is at zero. In the remainder of my talk, I will first discuss measures for
preventing deflation--the preferable option if feasible. I will then turn to
policy measures that the Fed and other government authorities can take if
prevention efforts fail and deflation appears to be gaining a foothold in the
economy.
Preventing
Deflation
As I
have already emphasized, deflation is generally the result of low and falling
aggregate demand. The basic prescription for preventing deflation is
therefore straightforward, at least in principle: Use monetary and fiscal
policy as needed to support aggregate spending, in a manner as nearly
consistent as possible with full utilization of economic resources and low
and stable inflation. In other words, the best way to get out of trouble is
not to get into it in the first place. Beyond this commonsense injunction,
however, there are several measures that the Fed (or any central bank) can
take to reduce the risk of falling into deflation.
First,
the Fed should try to preserve a buffer zone for the inflation rate, that is,
during normal times it should not try to push inflation down all the way to
zero.6 Most central banks seem to understand the need for a buffer zone. For
example, central banks with explicit inflation targets almost invariably set
their target for inflation above zero, generally between 1 and 3 percent per
year. Maintaining an inflation buffer zone reduces the risk that a large,
unanticipated drop in aggregate demand will drive the economy far enough into
deflationary territory to lower the nominal interest rate to zero. Of course,
this benefit of having a buffer zone for inflation must be weighed against
the costs associated with allowing a higher inflation rate in normal times.
Second,
the Fed should take most seriously--as of course it does--its responsibility
to ensure financial stability in the economy. Irving Fisher (1933) was
perhaps the first economist to emphasize the potential connections between
violent financial crises, which lead to "fire sales" of assets and
falling asset prices, with general declines in aggregate demand and the price
level. A healthy, well capitalized banking system and smoothly functioning
capital markets are an important line of defense against deflationary shocks.
The Fed should and does use its regulatory and supervisory powers to ensure
that the financial system will remain resilient if financial conditions
change rapidly. And at times of extreme threat to financial stability, the
Federal Reserve stands ready to use the discount window and other tools to
protect the financial system, as it did during the 1987 stock market crash
and the September 11, 2001, terrorist attacks.
NWE: I agree that some attention to financial system
capitalization is important. However, this doesn't mean giving money to
bankers willy-nilly. The debt/equity swap idea is consistent with the
principles of capitalism, and also consistent with the idea that the
government should actively avoid "systemic collapse" problems.
Third,
as suggested by a number of studies, when inflation is already low and the
fundamentals of the economy suddenly deteriorate, the central bank should act
more preemptively and more aggressively than usual in cutting rates
(Orphanides and Wieland, 2000; Reifschneider and Williams, 2000; Ahearne et
al., 2002). By moving decisively and early, the Fed may be able to prevent
the economy from slipping into deflation, with the special problems that
entails.
As I have indicated, I believe that the combination of strong economic
fundamentals and policymakers that are attentive to downside as well as
upside risks to inflation make significant deflation in the United States in
the foreseeable future quite unlikely. But suppose that, despite all
precautions, deflation were to take hold in the U.S. economy and, moreover,
that the Fed's policy instrument--the federal funds rate--were to fall to
zero. What then? In the remainder of my talk I will discuss some possible
options for stopping a deflation once it has gotten under way. I should
emphasize that my comments on this topic are necessarily speculative, as the
modern Federal Reserve has never faced this situation nor has it
pre-committed itself formally to any specific course of action should
deflation arise. Furthermore, the specific responses the Fed would undertake
would presumably depend on a number of factors, including its assessment of
the whole range of risks to the economy and any complementary policies being
undertaken by other parts of the U.S. government.7
NWE: Translated -- you want to devalue the currency really
quickly. Most currencies in the world were devauled around September 1931,
but economies bottomed around March 1933, eighteen months later. Bernanke,
echoing the conventional wisdom of his Keynesian buddies, is saying that you
want to start devaluing as quickly as possible.
Curing
Deflation
Let me
start with some general observations about monetary policy at the zero bound,
sweeping under the rug for the moment some technical and operational issues.
As I
have mentioned, some observers have concluded that when the central bank's
policy rate falls to zero--its practical minimum--monetary policy loses its
ability to further stimulate aggregate demand and the economy. At a broad
conceptual level, and in my view in practice as well, this conclusion is
clearly mistaken. Indeed, under a fiat (that is, paper) money system, a
government (in practice, the central bank in cooperation with other agencies)
should always be able to generate increased nominal spending and inflation,
even when the short-term nominal interest rate is at zero.
The
conclusion that deflation is always reversible under a fiat money system
follows from basic economic reasoning. A little parable may prove useful:
Today an ounce of gold sells for $300, more or less. Now suppose that a
modern alchemist solves his subject's oldest problem by finding a way to produce
unlimited amounts of new gold at essentially no cost. Moreover, his invention
is widely publicized and scientifically verified, and he announces his
intention to begin massive production of gold within days. What would happen
to the price of gold? Presumably, the potentially unlimited supply of cheap
gold would cause the market price of gold to plummet. Indeed, if the market
for gold is to any degree efficient, the price of gold would collapse
immediately after the announcement of the invention, before the alchemist had
produced and marketed a single ounce of yellow metal.
What
has this got to do with monetary policy? Like gold, U.S. dollars have value
only to the extent that they are strictly limited in supply. But the U.S.
government has a technology, called a printing press (or, today, its
electronic equivalent), that allows it to produce as many U.S. dollars as it
wishes at essentially no cost. By increasing the number of U.S. dollars in
circulation, or even by credibly threatening to do so, the U.S. government
can also reduce the value of a dollar in terms of goods and services, which
is equivalent to raising the prices in dollars of those goods and services.
We conclude that, under a paper-money system, a determined government can
always generate higher spending and hence positive inflation.
Of
course, the U.S. government is not going to print money and distribute it
willy-nilly (although as we will see later, there are practical policies that
approximate this behavior).8 Normally, money is injected into the economy
through asset purchases by the Federal Reserve. To stimulate aggregate
spending when short-term interest rates have reached zero, the Fed must
expand the scale of its asset purchases or, possibly, expand the menu of
assets that it buys. Alternatively, the Fed could find other ways of
injecting money into the system--for example, by making low-interest-rate
loans to banks or cooperating with the fiscal authorities. Each method of
adding money to the economy has advantages and drawbacks, both technical and
economic. One important concern in practice is that calibrating the economic
effects of nonstandard means of injecting money may be difficult, given our
relative lack of experience with such policies. Thus, as I have stressed
already, prevention of deflation remains preferable to having to cure it. If
we do fall into deflation, however, we can take comfort that the logic of the
printing press example must assert itself, and sufficient injections of money
will ultimately always reverse a deflation.
NWE: Note that his concept of deflation is closely linked to a
"falloff of aggregate demand." This means that they'll keep
printing until people shop more and companies hire more people. There are
some examples of this: in 1920s Germany, the unemployment rate was very low,
and people dumped their cash every day for real goods before the money lost
value overnight. However, in other cases like Zimbabwe today, the
unemployment rate can soar over 50% as the economy collapses from
hyperinflation.
So what
then might the Fed do if its target interest rate, the overnight federal
funds rate, fell to zero? One relatively straightforward extension of current
procedures would be to try to stimulate spending by lowering rates further
out along the Treasury term structure--that is, rates on government bonds of
longer maturities.9 There are at least two ways of bringing down longer-term
rates, which are complementary and could be employed separately or in
combination. One approach, similar to an action taken in the past couple of
years by the Bank of Japan, would be for the Fed to commit to holding the
overnight rate at zero for some specified period. Because long-term interest
rates represent averages of current and expected future short-term rates,
plus a term premium, a commitment to keep short-term rates at zero for some
time--if it were credible--would induce a decline in longer-term rates. A
more direct method, which I personally prefer, would be for the Fed to begin
announcing explicit ceilings for yields on longer-maturity Treasury debt
(say, bonds maturing within the next two years). The Fed could enforce these
interest-rate ceilings by committing to make unlimited purchases of
securities up to two years from maturity at prices consistent with the
targeted yields. If this program were successful, not only would yields on
medium-term Treasury securities fall, but (because of links operating through
expectations of future interest rates) yields on longer-term public and
private debt (such as mortgages) would likely fall as well.
NWE: Does that sound kinda like the recent Treasury bond and
MBS-buying fiesta.Oh, yes! I told you this guy is a one-trick pony.
Lower
rates over the maturity spectrum of public and private securities should
strengthen aggregate demand in the usual ways and thus help to end deflation.
Of course, if operating in relatively short-dated Treasury debt proved
insufficient, the Fed could also attempt to cap yields of Treasury securities
at still longer maturities, say three to six years. Yet another option would
be for the Fed to use its existing authority to operate in the markets for
agency debt (for example, mortgage-backed securities issued by Ginnie Mae,
the Government National Mortgage Association).
Historical
experience tends to support the proposition that a sufficiently determined
Fed can peg or cap Treasury bond prices and yields at other than the shortest
maturities. The most striking episode of bond-price pegging occurred during
the years before the Federal Reserve-Treasury Accord of 1951.10 Prior to that
agreement, which freed the Fed from its responsibility to fix yields on
government debt, the Fed maintained a ceiling of 2-1/2 percent on long-term
Treasury bonds for nearly a decade. Moreover, it simultaneously established a
ceiling on the twelve-month Treasury certificate of between 7/8 percent to
1-1/4 percent and, during the first half of that period, a rate of 3/8
percent on the 90-day Treasury bill. The Fed was able to achieve these low
interest rates despite a level of outstanding government debt (relative to
GDP) significantly greater than we have today, as well as inflation rates
substantially more variable. At times, in order to enforce these low rates,
the Fed had actually to purchase the bulk of outstanding 90-day bills. Interestingly,
though, the Fed enforced the 2-1/2 percent ceiling on long-term bond yields
for nearly a decade without ever holding a substantial share of long-maturity
bonds outstanding.11 For example, the Fed held 7.0 percent of outstanding
Treasury securities in 1945 and 9.2 percent in 1951 (the year of the Accord),
almost entirely in the form of 90-day bills. For comparison, in 2001 the Fed
held 9.7 percent of the stock of outstanding Treasury debt.
NWE: This is a little-known corner of U.S. economic history. The
U.S. government had taken on enormous debts of 125% of GDP during WWII. In
the late 1940s, immediately after the war, it attempted to keep yields on
this debt low by having the Fed make purchases as Bernanke describes. This
caused the dollar to weaken against gold. Britain was doing the same thing,
leading to a rather large devaluation in 1949. The Fed finally became Fed Up
in 1951 and said "No Mas." This saved the dollar. The Fed was
actually a bit of a protector of the gold standard during the 1950s and
1960s, under Mariner Eccles and William McChesney Martin.
To
repeat, I suspect that operating on rates on longer-term Treasuries would
provide sufficient leverage for the Fed to achieve its goals in most
plausible scenarios. If lowering yields on longer-dated Treasury securities
proved insufficient to restart spending, however, the Fed might next consider
attempting to influence directly the yields on privately issued securities.
Unlike some central banks, and barring changes to current law, the Fed is
relatively restricted in its ability to buy private securities directly.12
However, the Fed does have broad powers to lend to the private sector
indirectly via banks, through the discount window.13 Therefore a second
policy option, complementary to operating in the markets for Treasury and
agency debt, would be for the Fed to offer fixed-term loans to banks at low
or zero interest, with a wide range of private assets (including, among
others, corporate bonds, commercial paper, bank loans, and mortgages) deemed
eligible as collateral.14 For example, the Fed might make 90-day or 180-day
zero-interest loans to banks, taking corporate commercial paper of the same
maturity as collateral. Pursued aggressively, such a program could
significantly reduce liquidity and term premiums on the assets used as
collateral. Reductions in these premiums would lower the cost of capital both
to banks and the nonbank private sector, over and above the beneficial effect
already conferred by lower interest rates on government securities.15
NWE: Sounds kinda familiar.
The
Fed can inject money into the economy in still other ways. For example, the
Fed has the authority to buy foreign government debt, as well as domestic
government debt. Potentially, this class of assets offers huge scope for Fed
operations, as the quantity of foreign assets eligible for purchase by the
Fed is several times the stock of U.S. government debt.16
I need
to tread carefully here. Because the economy is a complex and interconnected system,
Fed purchases of the liabilities of foreign governments have the potential to
affect a number of financial markets, including the market for foreign
exchange. In the United States, the Department of the Treasury, not the
Federal Reserve, is the lead agency for making international economic policy,
including policy toward the dollar; and the Secretary of the Treasury has
expressed the view that the determination of the value of the U.S. dollar
should be left to free market forces. Moreover, since the United States is a
large, relatively closed economy, manipulating the exchange value of the
dollar would not be a particularly desirable way to fight domestic deflation,
particularly given the range of other options available. Thus, I want to be
absolutely clear that I am today neither forecasting nor recommending any
attempt by U.S. policymakers to target the international value of the dollar.
NWE: Keynesians love this sort of rationale because it helps them
avoid blame for the inevitable effects of their inflationary policies. The
decline of the dollar is the fault of "free market forces!" I
betcha we're going to hear more about this in coming months.
Although
a policy of intervening to affect the exchange value of the dollar is nowhere
on the horizon today, it's worth noting that there have been times when
exchange rate policy has been an effective weapon against deflation. A
striking example from U.S. history is Franklin Roosevelt's 40 percent
devaluation of the dollar against gold in 1933-34, enforced by a program of
gold purchases and domestic money creation. The devaluation and the rapid
increase in money supply it permitted ended the U.S. deflation remarkably
quickly. Indeed, consumer price inflation in the United States, year on year,
went from -10.3 percent in 1932 to -5.1 percent in 1933 to 3.4 percent in
1934.17 The economy grew strongly, and by the way, 1934 was one of the best
years of the century for the stock market. If nothing else, the episode
illustrates that monetary actions can have powerful effects on the economy,
even when the nominal interest rate is at or near zero, as was the case at
the time of Roosevelt's devaluation.
Fiscal
Policy
Each
of the policy options I have discussed so far involves the Fed's acting on
its own. In practice, the effectiveness of anti-deflation policy could be
significantly enhanced by cooperation between the monetary and fiscal
authorities. A broad-based tax cut, for example, accommodated by a program of
open-market purchases to alleviate any tendency for interest rates to
increase, would almost certainly be an effective stimulant to consumption and
hence to prices. Even if households decided not to increase consumption but
instead re-balanced their portfolios by using their extra cash to acquire
real and financial assets, the resulting increase in asset values would lower
the cost of capital and improve the balance sheet positions of potential
borrowers. A money-financed tax cut is essentially equivalent to Milton
Friedman's famous "helicopter drop" of money.18
NWE: The real advantages of a tax cut would be the lowered
barriers to commerce. "Putting money in people's pockets" is
largely irrelevant except for the very short term.
Of
course, in lieu of tax cuts or increases in transfers the government could
increase spending on current goods and services or even acquire existing real
or financial assets. If the Treasury issued debt to purchase private assets
and the Fed then purchased an equal amount of Treasury debt with newly
created money, the whole operation would be the economic equivalent of direct
open-market operations in private assets.
Japan
The
claim that deflation can be ended by sufficiently strong action has no doubt
led you to wonder, if that is the case, why has Japan not ended its
deflation?
The
Japanese situation is a complex one that I cannot fully discuss today. I will
just make two brief, general points.
First,
as you know, Japan's economy faces some significant barriers to growth
besides deflation, including massive financial problems in the banking and
corporate sectors and a large overhang of government debt. Plausibly,
private-sector financial problems have muted the effects of the monetary
policies that have been tried in Japan, even as the heavy overhang of
government debt has made Japanese policymakers more reluctant to use
aggressive fiscal policies (for evidence see, for example, Posen, 1998).
Fortunately, the U.S. economy does not share these problems, at least not to
anything like the same degree, suggesting that anti-deflationary monetary and
fiscal policies would be more potent here than they have been in Japan.
NWE: A big pile of blah-blah. Actually, the solution for
"deflation" in Japan was exactly what he just described, namely,
printing some money to depress the too-high value of the currency.
Second,
and more important, I believe that, when all is said and done, the failure to
end deflation in Japan does not necessarily reflect any technical
infeasibility of achieving that goal. Rather, it is a byproduct of a
longstanding political debate about how best to address Japan's overall
economic problems. As the Japanese certainly realize, both restoring banks
and corporations to solvency and implementing significant structural change
are necessary for Japan's long-run economic health. [NWE:
Structural change! This was always the last resort of people who haven't a
clue. If you want to see what I mean, just ask them what kind of structural change?]
But in the short run, comprehensive economic reform will likely impose large
costs on many, for example, in the form of unemployment or bankruptcy. As a
natural result, politicians, economists, businesspeople, and the general
public in Japan have sharply disagreed about competing proposals for reform.
In the resulting political deadlock, strong policy actions are discouraged,
and cooperation among policymakers is difficult to achieve.
NWE: Didn't he just say you could cure deflation with the printing
press? This was the actual, proper solution for monetary deflation in Japan,
and the U.S. in 2002.
In
short, Japan's deflation problem is real and serious; but, in my view,
political constraints, rather than a lack of policy instruments, explain why
its deflation has persisted for as long as it has. Thus, I do not view the
Japanese experience as evidence against the general conclusion that U.S.
policymakers have the tools they need to prevent, and, if necessary, to cure
a deflationary recession in the United States.
Conclusion
Sustained
deflation can be highly destructive to a modern economy and should be strongly
resisted. Fortunately, for the foreseeable future, the chances of a serious
deflation in the United States appear remote indeed, in large part because of
our economy's underlying strengths but also because of the determination of
the Federal Reserve and other U.S. policymakers to act preemptively against
deflationary pressures. Moreover, as I have discussed today, a variety of
policy responses are available should deflation appear to be taking hold.
Because some of these alternative policy tools are relatively less familiar,
they may raise practical problems of implementation and of calibration of
their likely economic effects. For this reason, as I have emphasized,
prevention of deflation is preferable to cure. Nevertheless, I hope to have
persuaded you that the Federal Reserve and other economic policymakers would
be far from helpless in the face of deflation, even should the federal funds
rate hit its zero bound.19
NWE: What happens when Bernanke's One Trick doesn't work? I
suppose we'll find out.
* * *
Take
Delivery: As you know, I am a proponent of taking
delivery on gold-related assets. Don't just sit around with GLD or futures,
total return swaps or some other paper nonsense, and hope everything works
out right because it did in the past. Recently, others have been coming to
the same conclusion. The German government has been taking delivery of all
gold held custodially outside of Germany (mostly U.S. and U.K.), as well as
their various gold swap agreements with the U.S. The UAE is in the process of
taking delivery on huge quantities of Middle East-owned gold stored mostly in
London, and transferring it to a new depository located in Dubai. I'm certain
the Chinese are taking delivery on the large additions to official gold
reserves they recently announced. Deliveries on the Comex have soared in
recent months, leading to some very
strange warehouse numbers. There have been a couple of million-plus ounce
delivery months in gold, but the warehouse numbers show hardly any gold
entering or leaving the warehouses, or even changing hands between dealer and
customer inventories. Comex rules require that all physical deliveries are
settled through their warehouses. What am I saying? I'm saying that the Comex
warehouse numbers might
be lies intended to make you think that there is more gold there than there
is -- gold necessary to support the notion that futures
contracts are "gold equivalent." As it is, Deutschebank avoided
default on almost 1m oz. worth of futures contracts in March via direct ECB
intervention. The ECB sold them the gold so they could deliver. What happens
when the next guy who gets 1m oz. behind on a short futures position? Why
take the chance? Germany, UAE and China aren't. And they would know, don't
you think?
The
chit chat right now is that June deliveries are a concern on the Comex, and
that a commercial short is in trouble (like Deutschebank was). We'll see if
something happens.
* * *
The
chorus for "more inflation" rises:
U.S. Needs More Inflation to Speed Recovery, Say Mankiw, Rogoff
AEI: Why Not Negative Interest Rates?
* * *
What's
wrong with devaluation? Currency devaulation actually
works -- in other words, it mostly delivers the results that its proponents
claim. On balance, debts become easier to service, which reduces the
incidence of bankruptcy. People might tend to buy a little more, because the
decline in currency value means the "real" price of things falls.
Unemployment may fall, or at least rise less quickly, because wages are
effectively reduced. Exporters gain a competitive advantage, and domestic
industries also enjoy an advantages versus foreign competitors. Over six
months, you might see a real advantage to inflation/devaluation. As
economists in the past have discovered, this works mostly due to "money
illusion," or the fact that people treat the currency as a stable constant
even though it is demonstrably not. As people become accustomed to dealing
with a currency that constantly loses value, as is quite common throughout
the developing world, they are not fooled by the government's latest currency
tricks.
The
problem of devaluation tends to lie in the longer term. "You can't
devalue your way to prosperity," it is said. Let's see what
this looks like in statistical terms:
Personal
Income, from the GDP statistics, in gold oz. We have iPhones today, but we
aren't actually any wealthier than the mid-1950s. Is the average (median)
middle-class family better off today than the average family of the 1950s? Obviously NOT.
Corporate
profits haven't really gone anywhere either -- even despite a larger
population.
* * *
Some
cover scans of the foreign language versions of my book. Apparently it is
quite a hit in Korea! (I don't have the French version yet -- working on it.)
Nathan
Lewis
Nathan
Lewis was formerly the chief international economist of a leading economic
forecasting firm. He now works in asset management. Lewis has written for the
Financial Times, the Wall Street Journal Asia, the Japan Times, Pravda, and
other publications. He has appeared on financial television in the United
States, Japan, and the Middle East. About the Book: Gold: The Once and Future
Money (Wiley, 2007, ISBN: 978-0-470-04766-8, $27.95) is available at
bookstores nationwide, from all major online booksellers, and direct from the
publisher at www.wileyfinance.com or 800-225-5945. In Canada, call
800-567-4797.
|
|