San Francisco Fed president John Williams has been yapping about the need
for interest rate hikes, 4% inflation targets, and Fed-set GDP growth
targets.
Williams is bullish on jobs. He also says the US economy is at “full
strength” but inflation needs to be higher now so we can cut rates later.
His speech to the Hayek Group in Reno Nevada was called Whither Inflation Targeting? Here are some excerpts:
Good evening; it’s a pleasure to be here to discuss the economy and
monetary policy with the Hayek Group. I’ll start with a quick overview of the
U.S. economic outlook and what it means for monetary policy. Spoiler alert:
The punch line is that the economy has climbed back to full strength, and it
therefore makes sense to move monetary policy gradually back to normal. That
brings me to the second topic of my talk: What is “normal” monetary policy?
Our goal is not to have an unemployment rate of zero. Instead, it’s to be
near the “natural rate” of unemployment: That’s the rate we can expect in a
healthy economy. It’s impossible to know exactly what that number is, but
economists generally put it between 4¾ and 5 percent today.1 With the
unemployment rate at 4.9 percent, we’re right on target.
Turning to the other side of the ledger, the Fed’s monetary policy
committee—the Federal Open Market Committee, or FOMC for short—has set a
long-run goal of 2 percent inflation. Inflation has been running persistently
below that goal for several years.
We’re not quite at our target yet, but the combination of fading
transitory factors and a strong economy should help us get back to our 2
percent goal in the next year or two.
To sum up, I remain confident about the road we are on.
What it Means for Interest Rates
So, what does this mean for interest rates? In the context of a strong
economy with good momentum, it makes sense to get back to a pace of gradual
rate increases, preferably sooner rather than later. Let me be clear: In arguing
for an increase in interest rates, I’m not trying to stall the economic
expansion. It’s just the opposite: My aim is to keep it on a sound footing so
it can be sustained for a long time.
History teaches us that an economy that runs too hot for too long can
generate imbalances, potentially leading to excessive inflation, asset market
bubbles, and ultimately economic correction and recession. A gradual process
of raising rates reduces the risks of such an outcome.
What is Normal Monetary Policy?
New realities pose significant challenges for the conduct of monetary
policy in the United States and elsewhere. Foremost is the significant
decline in the natural rate of interest, or r* (r-star), over the past
quarter-century to historically low levels.
The daunting challenge for central banks is how to deliver stable
inflation in a low r-star world. This conundrum shares some characteristics
and common roots with the theory of secular stagnation; in both scenarios,
interest rates, growth, and inflation are persistently low.
How Low Can Rates Stay?
In a recent paper, Kathryn Holston, Thomas Laubach, and I estimated the
inflation-adjusted natural rate for four major economies: the United States,
Canada, the euro area, and the United Kingdom. In 1990, estimates ranged from
about 2½ to 3½ percent. By 2007, on the eve of the global financial crisis,
these had all declined to between 2 and 2½ percent. By 2015, all four
estimates had dropped sharply, to 1½ percent for Canada and the United
Kingdom, nearly zero for the United States, and below zero for the euro area.
The critical implication of a lower natural rate of interest is that
conventional monetary policy has less room to stimulate the economy during an
economic downturn, owing to a lower bound on how low interest rates can go.
This will necessitate a greater reliance on unconventional tools like central
bank balance sheets, forward guidance, and potentially even negative policy
rates.
In this new normal, recessions will tend to be longer and deeper,
recoveries slower, and the risks of unacceptably low inflation and the
ultimate loss of the nominal anchor will be higher. We have already gotten a
first taste of the effects of a low r-star, with uncomfortably low inflation
and growth despite very low interest rates. Unfortunately, if the status quo
endures, the future is likely to hold more of the same—with the possibility
of even more severe challenges to maintaining price stability and full
employment.
Low R-Star and Strategies for Mitigation
There are actions that central banks and governments can undertake to
avoid this fate. These include fiscal and other policies aimed at raising the
natural interest rate, as well as alternative monetary, fiscal, and other
policies that are more likely to succeed in maintaining a strong economy and
stable inflation in the face of a low natural rate.
Although inflation targeting central banks that aimed for a low inflation
rate generally have been successful at stabilizing inflation in the past,
such an approach is not as well-suited for a low r-star era. There simply may
not be enough room for central banks to cut interest rates in response to an
economic downturn when both natural rates and inflation are very low.
The most direct attack on low r-star would be for central banks to pursue
a somewhat higher inflation target. This would imply a higher average level
of interest rates and thereby give monetary policy more room to maneuver. The
logic of this approach argues that a 1 percentage point increase in the
inflation target would offset the deleterious effects of an equal-sized
decline in r-star.
A second alternative would be to replace the inflation target with a
flexible price-level or nominal GDP target, where the central bank targets a
steadily growing level of prices or nominal GDP, rather than the rate of
inflation.
Because they provide a clear metric by which to judge whether the economy
is above or below the stipulated goal, they may help improve the systematic
conduct of policy and its communication and public understanding, especially
when interest rates are constrained by the lower bound.
Of course, like a higher inflation target, these approaches also have
potential disadvantages that must be carefully scrutinized when considering
their relative costs and benefits.
Time is not on our side. We have witnessed the extreme difficulties of
achieving price stability and full employment with a low r-star. I firmly
believe that now is the time for experts and policymakers around the world to
actively study and assess the pros and cons of alternative proposals, so that
we are better prepared for the challenges related to persistently low natural
real rates of interest.
Down the Rabbit Hole Synopsis
- Williams says the “economy is at full strength”. I point
out the last four quarters of real GDP are 2.0%, 0.9%, 0.8%, and 1.1%.
Is that full strength?
- Williams admits “It’s impossible to know exactly the
natural rate of employment” but he is content to guess.
- Williams does not admit it’s impossible to know
the “natural interest rate” and he wildly guesses at that.
- Williams seeks to defeat the natural interest rate
because he knows it needs to be higher. Natural just is not good enough.
- Williams proposes a higher interest rate target of 3% to
4%. Purportedly, just having a higher target will perform magic wonders.
I ask a simple question to Williams, the Bank of Japan, and the ECB: “If
you cannot hit a 2% target how the hell can you hit 4%?”
- Williams says because we need higher inflation, we need
to hike now so the economy does not overheat.
- Williams also wants to hike now so we can cut rates
later. That implies we cannot get to 4%! Alternatively, it implies
Williams would cut rates to avoid recession even if inflation was at 4%.
The logical conclusion is 8% inflation would be the next target.
- Williams mentioned debt deflation. Lovely. The chief
sponsor of debt deflation is central bank wizardly. They do not count
asset bubble inflation in their measures.
Counterproductive Policies
The hubris of Williams is amazing. He claims to be able to figure out the
“natural rate of interest”, which he cannot do, then he believes he is
smart enough to know by what degree the Fed should circumvent it.
Williams mentions bubbles but cannot see the massive bubbles in front of
his face.
Price Deflation Should be Welcome
There is no credible evidence that people put off buying something because
prices are falling. Those who need a coat, a computer, or a car will buy one.
If your computer or toaster goes out, you throw it away and buy another. If
your gas tank needs filling, you fill it. If prices are low enough, impulse
buying goes up, not down.
Inflation expectation theory widely believed by central bankers is total
nonsense.
Asset Deflation Not CPI Deflation!
It’s asset deflation not CPI deflation that central banks ought to fear.
Even the BIS agrees with that statement. For discussion please see Historical Perspective on CPI Deflations: How Damaging are
They?
Economic Challenge to Keynesians
Of all the widely believed but patently false economic beliefs is the
absurd notion that falling consumer prices are bad for the economy and
something must be done about them.
I have commented on this many times and have been vindicated not only by
sound economic theory but also by actual historical examples.
My January 20, 2015 post Deflation Bonanza! (And the Fool’s Mission to Stop It)
has a good synopsis.
And my Challenge to Keynesians “Prove Rising Prices Provide an
Overall Economic Benefit” has gone unanswered.
In their attempts to fight routine consumer price deflation, central
bankers create very destructive asset bubbles that eventually collapse,
setting off what they should fear – asset bubble deflations following a
buildup of bank credit on inflated assets.
Risks of Low Inflation
Williams worries about “low inflation”.
The only risk associated with falling consumer prices is the 100%
likelihood that central bankers will attempt to do something ridiculous in
response!
The convoluted thinking of San Francisco Fed president John Williams is a
prime example.
Mike “Mish” Shedlock