|
In a report on fixed income, David Owen, Chief European Financial Economist at Jefferies,
notes that demand for credit in Europe has plunged.
Owen asks Is it the supply or demand for credit that matters?
25 April 2012
Perhaps the most memorable comment Mario Draghi made to the European
Parliament today was the need for a euro area Growth Pact, but he did draw
comfort from the results of the ECB’s latest Bank Lending survey.
Draghi made reference to the fact that the balance of firms tightening credit
conditions had fallen (from 35% in January to 9%). However, that it is not to
say that credit conditions are actually easing, just that they are no longer
tightening at the same rate as in January.
Not only are credit conditions still tightening, albeit at a slower rate, but
importantly the ECB’s latest Bank Lending survey shows credit demand
collapsing. This is not something that Mario Draghi mentioned to the European
Parliament at all.
Europe Faces Japan Syndrome
In reference to the above chart, Ambrose Evans-Pritchard at The Telegraph
says Europe faces Japan syndrome as credit demand implodes
Europe (minus Germany) looks more like
post-bubble Japan each month.
The long-feared credit crunch has mutated instead into a collapse in DEMAND
for loans. Households and firms are comatose, or scared stiff, in a string of
countries.
Demand for housing loans fell 70pc in Portugal, 44pc in Italy, and 42pc in
the Netherlands in the first quarter of 2012. Enterprise loans fell 38pc in
Italy. The survey took place in late March and early April, and therefore
includes the second of Mario Draghi’s €1 trillion liquidity
infusion (LTRO).
The ECB said net demand for loans had fallen "to a significantly lower
level than had been expected in the fourth quarter of 2011, with the decline
driven in particular by a further sharp drop in financing needs for fixed
investment." Demand fell 43pc for household loans, and 30pc for non-bank
firms.
This slump in loan demand is more or less what happened during Japan’s
Lost Decade as Mr and Mrs Watanabe shunned debt. Zero interest rates did
nothing. The Bank of Japan was "pushing on a string" (though it
never really launched bond purchases with any serious determination).
The credit squeeze is entirely predictable – and was widely predicted
– given that banks must raise their core Tier 1 capital ratios to 9pc
by July to meet EU rules, or face nationalisation. (The pro-cyclical folly of
this beggars belief: by all means impose higher buffers, but not during a
recession, and not by letting banks slash their balance sheets. The US at
least forced its banks to raise capital, an entirely different policy since
it does not lead to a lending crunch.)
The IMF said last week that Europe’s banks would slash their balance
sheets by €2 trillion – or 7pc – by next year. This amounts
to an economic shock. The Fund said deleveraging on this scale at a time of
sharp fiscal tightening risks a "bad equilibrium".
Or one analyst said, the LTRO lets northern banks dump their bond holdings
onto Club Med banks. The renationalisation of the eurozone financial system
goes a step further.
The LTRO "carry trade" is already revealing the sting in its tail
in any case since the banks are by now underwater on a lot of bonds. What
happens if and when they need to sell those bonds to cover debts falling due
over the next year?
Until the ECB conducts monetary policy with proper energy, calls for
"Growth Compacts" from governments amount to humbug. The ECB needs
to do its own work.
We all know why it will not do so: because Hayekian romantics at the
Bundesbank hold sway, and none of the other governors dare say boo. Live with
the consequences.
Live with the Consequences Indeed
Pritchard conveniently ignores the fact that Japan is struggling right now to
"live with the consequences" of numerous misguided monetary and
fiscal stimulus efforts over 20 years. Japan has debt-to-GDP exceeding 200%
and little to show for it. And Japan now has to live with the consequences of
numerous misguided QE and stimulus proposals.
Pritchard apparently wants more QE for Europe as if that would increase
demand for credit.
Note that two rounds of QE did not increase the demand for credit in the US
as per my post The Real Consumer Credit Story: Virtually No Recovery in
Revolving Credit, No Recovery in Non-Revolving Credit.
Moreover, QE did not succeed in increasing the demand for credit in Japan
over 20 years. So pray tell why would QE increase the demand for credit in
Europe? More importantly, even if it did, would that be a good thing?
European banks are already over-leveraged and under-capitalized so how the
hell is providing cheap credit going to possibly do anything good?
Would 0% interest rates help when that did not help Japan?
Pritchard Misses the Boat
Clearly Pritchard missed the boat on QE as well as the desirability of
attempting to cram more credit down banks' throats when banks are
over-leveraged and under-capitalized.
Everyone wants to do something "but not now". While there is
immense merit to not hiking taxes in a recession as Brussels forced on
Greece, Spain, and Portugal, work rule and pension changes are badly needed.
Pritchard's idea of raising capital instead of selling assets seems
reasonable enough. However, nothing stops banks from doing that, at least in
theory. Is practice another matter?
Giant Sucking Sound
William Wright discusses Tier-1 Capital requirements in A rough guide to surviving the great deleveraging of
2012
As if Basel III weren’t enough of a
headache, big European banks face a deadline of June 30 from the European
Banking Authority to increase their core Tier-1 capital ratios to 9%,
equivalent to raising €115bn in equity.
In theory, banks can meet this by retaining profits, raising equity or
shrinking assets. But with equity markets all but closed to banks and
earnings falling, a crash diet to reduce their bloated balance sheets is the
only realistic option.
Analysts expect that the great bank deleveraging of 2012 could see as much as
$2 trillion to $3 trillion of assets trimmed from European banks’
balance sheets – or about 5% of total assets – with damaging
consequences not only for the banking industry but for the fragile European
economy.
Here is a rough guide to some of the inevitable consequences – some
deliberate, some unintended and some obscure – of this deleveraging on
the investment banking industry.
Death of profits, jobs and banks
The most obvious impact of deleveraging will be the devastation it will wreak
on the profits of investment banks. In 2006, Goldman Sachs posted a return on
equity of 33% and its core leverage – assets divided by equity –
was 29 times. Fast forward to the first nine months of this year, and its
return on equity was 3.7% with leverage of 14 times. Not because it has
radically shrunk its balance sheet (yet) but because it has more than doubled
its equity.
The same process will play out across the industry, where the combination of
an increase in the cost of business driven by regulation is colliding with a
downturn in activity. This will choke off profits, with JP Morgan forecasting
that average ROE for the industry will fall to just 8% next year.
That’s in line with research by Financial News that shows average
pretax ROE in the first nine months of this year was 12% (or about 8% net).
Structurally lower profitability has already prompted banks such as Credit
Suisse and UBS to slash their fixed income trading activities. While the
thousands of job cuts seem harsh, they are often in the low single digits in
terms of overall headcount. As more banks grasp the nettle in 2012, they will
pull out of entire business lines, cutting 10% or 20% of their staff –
or pull out of investment banking altogether.
Is That All Bad News?
Wright concludes that is not all bad news. I agree, but for some different
reasons.
First Wright ...
The Promised Land
In all of this, there is some good news. For those banks that can survive the
rigours of deleveraging without having to pull out of entire regions or
businesses while retaining a profitable operation, there is a Promised Land
on the other side. Overcapacity in the investment banking industry will be
whittled away to leave a smaller number of bigger and (relatively) more
profitable global banks whose scale will increasingly play to their
advantage.
Bankers talk of JP Morgan, Deutsche Bank, Goldman Sachs and perhaps one other
– maybe Bank of America Merrill Lynch, Barclays Capital or Citi –
emerging stronger than ever. At the same time there will be a larger number
of product and sector specialists, which will drop the “me-too”
approach of the past decade.
In this new world, with a realistic price for risk and credit and less
competition, margins can only go one way: up.
Banks
Should Be Banks, Not Hedge Funds
I do not believe that bigger is better and I am sick of the notion "too
big to fail". Indeed, it most often means two things:
1.
Too
Big To Succeed
2.
Taxpayer
Bailouts
Banks should be banks, not hedge funds. To the extent that Basel III forces
banks to shed trading activities and other non-traditional activities that
banks now find themselves in, I view that as a good thing.
I certainly agree with Wright regarding the need for "a
realistic price for risk and credit", but "less competition"
is certainly not the essence of well-formed free markets.
My conclusion is that Wright does not understand the Fed's role in the
creation of this mess or sound Austrian economic principles needed to fix it.
We will indeed see a "a realistic price for risk and credit" if and
only if we get rid of the Fed and end fractional reserve lending. Bigger
banks are not the answer.
By the way, Wright is not quite correct when he says "equity markets
all but closed to banks".
Let's phrase the idea properly: "equity markets all but closed to
banks, on terms that banks want". Banks do not want shareholder
dilution that comes with raising equity now.
Bondholders do not want to take a hit either. Both should have happened
already. However, Bush, Obama, Congress, and the Fed acted in unison to
prevent what desperately needed to happen.
If Not Now, When?
Pritchard thinks the time to raise Tier-1 Capital requirements is not now.
OK, when is it? 10 years from now? Or will Spain, Greece, and Italy still be
too fragile?
Japan shows the folly of depending on QE and fiscal stimulus to spawn
inflation, then waiting for it to happen.
Japan's Four-Pronged Approach
1.
Fiscal
Stimulus
2.
Monetary
Stimulus (QE)
3.
Misguided
Hope
4.
Ignore
Capital Impairments of Banks Waiting for Things to Get Better
Did Japan succeed?
In the case of Europe, there is also this "not-so-little" problem
that Pritchard is extremely aware of yet mysteriously avoids every time he
rails about the ECB not doing enough. I am obviously talking about the Euro.
The LTRO increased leverage and risk on Spanish and Italian banks. QE is
useless, something Pritchard should see. Reducing interest rates will shift
imbalances to other countries, and may send oil and food prices higher, but
it sure will not increase lending.
Pritchard says "The ECB needs to do its own work, with proper energy."
What "work" is that? Does any "work" make any sense?
The first irony is Pritchard compares Europe to Japan, while essentially
proposing the same four-pronged policy of failure followed by Japan.
The second irony of Pritchard's column is that if Basel III moves forward the
date of the inevitable breakup of the eurozone, that would be a good thing. A
eurozone breakup would place Europe on a faster pace of ending the very
"Japan Syndrome" that Pritchard rails against.
Proper Energy
Not only do I want to raise tier-1 capital requirements, I want to see a 100%
gold-backed dollar, the end of fractional reserve lending, and the end of
duration-mismatched lending (e.g. selling 5-year CDs and making mortgage
loans for 30 years).
Finally, lending of money that is supposed to be available on demand is
fraudulent and must be stopped. I would be more than willing to phase those
ideas in, but the time to start is now, not 10 years from now under the
misguided notion things will be better if only banks would lend more.
|
|