|
A former Fed chairman addresses the country on national TV
(fiction):
“There should be a sign on the front of the Fed building in Washington
saying, ‘We work for the elites – the commercial bankers and government – at
the expense of everyone else. Try and stop us.’
“Bankers and politicians have had a mutually rewarding
relationship for ages. Bankers create money and loan it out at interest,
which can be very profitable. Trouble is, creating money electronically or
with a printing press, which is what central banks do, is counterfeiting. In
return for a share of the newly-created money, government lets banks get away
with it. Government gets bigger, bankers get richer.
“Bank counterfeiting, which is another name for inflation,
fuels a great many evils for which it gets little credit, such as wars and
depressions. To put an end to this racket we need to establish a free market
in banking, which means open it up to competition. What would prevent banks
from counterfeiting on a free market? Property right enforcement. All money
is someone’s property. If I deposit my money in a bank and pay a fee for the
service, I expect to be able to get it back on demand. If the bank can’t
provide it because the bank’s loaned it to someone else, it has violated my
property rights. If the law respects property rights consistently, the law
will hold the bank responsible. In the long run at least, counterfeiting
would be unprofitable. Few bankers will find such prospects tempting.
“Money was founded on the market. At first it was a
commodity that was bartered for other commodities or services. But because of
the great number of people willing to accept it in trade, it began to be
acquired for trading purposes only – as a medium of exchange, or money.
"Gold won the competition as the most popular money
long ago. Gold is very difficult to produce, which is one of the biggest
reasons it became the preferred medium of exchange. When a rare commodity
such as gold is used for money, the supply remains fairly constant.
"People have always known that increasing the money
supply dilutes the value of each monetary unit. But apparently they didn’t
make a connection between this fact and government’s eagerness to adopt a
fiat dollar as our monetary standard. When new money is created as a matter
of policy, as it has been for generations with the encouragement of leading
economists, the dollar is doomed, and so are dollar users.
“We need to remember, though, that banking as such is
crucial to higher civilization. As one commentator has astutely observed,
without an international banking system most of us wouldn’t be alive today.
Money and banking make possible the division of labor, which has drastically
reduced child mortality and raised living standards wherever free markets
flourished.
"But it’s also true that throughout most of banking
history, banks promised to redeem their notes in some precious metal, either
gold or silver. Though they could keep that promise for only a small fraction
of their customers, it still served as a vital check on their propensity to
counterfeit.
“For Americans, the gold standard was killed by
presidential decree during the crisis of the Great Depression. In 1971
another president told foreigners they could no longer get gold for American
dollars and thus removed the last trace of monetary gold from international
trade. Since then all governments have been on a fiat money standard,
depreciating their currencies as a matter of policy.
“The story of gold’s disappearance is part of a larger
narrative about the growth of government. Besides being a check on bank
counterfeiting, or inflation, gold is also a serious restriction on
government expansion. For the advocates of big government, therefore, gold
becomes a barbarous relic that stands in their way.
“The corruption of money began when people started keeping
their gold with banks, which would issue deposit receipts, or banknotes, as
money-substitutes. Because of the banker’s reputation for trust and
propriety, their notes were readily acceptable in trade as substitutes for
the gold locked away in their vaults. People knew they could redeem the notes
for gold any time they wished. But because of the convenience of carrying and
doing business with banknotes rather than coins, people tended to leave their
gold in the bank.
“Bankers became the money centers of their communities,
even though most of the money under their protection wasn’t theirs – they
could only claim a small percentage of it as a fee for their service. Because
money was in their possession, though, businessmen would come to them for
loans, and the bankers, seeking additional profit opportunities, found ways
to accommodate them.
“Unfortunately, they turned to counterfeiting as a means
of accommodation. What I mean is, they began creating and loaning out deposit
receipts that had no gold behind them. The new notes were counterfeit because
they were being passed off with the understanding that they were genuine gold
substitutes. But in fact the notes only looked like the real thing. The
bankers knew, though, that as long as they didn’t issue too many of these
counterfeit bills, they would escape detection.
“In extending loans with counterfeit notes or by creating
unbacked deposit accounts, they could point to conspicuous growth in the
local economy. According to almost everything we read, bankers weren’t
committing fraud, they were helping business grow, putting people to work,
helping them earn a living. As businessmen, the bankers could tell themselves
they were merely reacting to the demands of the market, in their case a
demand for money. And they reacted by simply printing and issuing it.
“Looking back, most commentators now find little fault
with what they were doing. So what if their notes weren’t backed by gold?
Today’s financial press would say the bankers were ‘investing’ or
‘accommodating’ or ‘providing liquidity.’ You never hear anyone call it counterfeiting,
at least not in mainstream circles.
“But by issuing banknotes or credit not covered by gold,
the bankers were increasing the money supply, a process identical in its
effects to counterfeiting. An increase in the supply of money confers no broad
social benefits – but it does benefit early users of the new money at the
expense of others: the first users have the advantage of buying goods at
current prices. Later, when prices have gone up, the inflated money supply
doesn’t benefit anyone. We improve the general welfare by increasing the
production of goods, not by increasing the production of money.
“Nevertheless, the banks’ practice of generating unbacked
money substitutes prevailed. Invariably, some would go too far and cause
depositors to begin doubting their banker’s rectitude. A few would start
showing up at teller windows wanting their notes exchanged for gold. Other
note holders would catch on, and the bank was soon confronted with a run. But
without enough gold to redeem, many of the banks had to shut their doors. As
the panic spread, even the more cautious banks would experience massive
demands for redemption.
“For reasons of its own, government took a strong interest
in the bankers’ plight and usually issued moratoriums on note redemption. For
a period sometimes lasting years, banks were permitted to default on their
liabilities to note holders while being allowed to conduct all other banking
activities.
“Helpful as this privilege was, it wasn’t enough. Banks
weren’t always allowed to renege on their promises, their easy credit
policies created bankruptcies and recessions, and besides, bank runs were
embarrassing. No banker liked seeing crowds swarming at his door demanding
what was theirs, even if the law was on his side.
“Fortunately for American bankers and their political
allies, Europe provided examples of ingenious solutions to the dilemma of
bank counterfeiting. During the early years of the twentieth century U. S.
bankers imported some of their ideas and, together with a few powerful
politicians, devised a plan for a banking cartel.
“The cartel would consist of all the national banks of the
country organized under the authority of a central bank, which would be
endowed by government with a monopoly of the note issue. Furthermore, all the
deposits of the member banks would be moved to the central bank and held as
reserves, with the central bank dictating to its members what fraction of its
reserves they had to maintain when making loans. Historically, banks have
been held to a ten percent reserve requirement most of the time, meaning they
could extend nine dollars in loans for every dollar held in reserve. By
dictating reserve ratios for all members, the central bank would control the
rate of monetary inflation in a uniform manner so that any one bank wouldn’t
get more reckless than the others and get itself and the rest of the banks in
trouble.
“Americans didn’t like cartels or centralized power, the
planners realized, so they called their creature a ‘reserve system’ instead
of a banking cartel and dressed it up with regional branches to avoid the
appearance of a concentration of power. As John Kenneth Galbraith observed
many years later, the regional design was ingenious for serving local pride
‘and for lulling the suspicions of the agrarians.’ Since no cartel will work
without government guns, it was natural, perhaps, to attach the name
‘federal’ to it, as well. Thus, the American central bank became known as the
Federal Reserve System, or the Fed.
“Signed into law on December 23, 1913, the Federal Reserve
Act was hailed as a major victory of the Progressive Era’s fight against the
alleged abuses of concentrated market power, in this case, the Money Trust.
Banking was at last rescued from the hands of Wall Street and put under the
enlightened care of government. Greed had been tamed by the people through
their selfless representatives in Congress and their man in the White House.
Government would see that the Fed served the ‘public interest’ and would
ensure that it didn’t fail. And with the Fed providing the economy with an
‘elastic currency,’ the ruinous panics and depressions of the past would be
gone forever.
“Those were the beliefs, but the facts reveal a far
different story.
“It was the Morgans and Rockefellers of Wall Street who
turned to government to cage their banking competition, especially the
growing challenge from non-national banks in the South and West, and came up
with a plan for a central bank. It was the big bankers who took the lead in
creating a system that would protect them from the hazards of bank
counterfeiting and make them a monopoly issuer of bank notes. After the Act
became law, it was Morgan bankers who occupied the seats of power in the new
system, particularly at the Fed’s New York branch where Benjamin Strong,
president of J. P. Morgan’s Bankers Trust Company, ran the money machine from
the Fed’s inception in 1914 to his death in 1928.
“The Fed became an indispensable instrument of profit and
power. Beginning in 1914, it cut reserve requirements approximately in half,
dropping the ratio from 21 percent to 11 percent, roughly doubling the money
supply and permitting both financial aid to the Allies and eventual American
entry into the European war. Under the impetus of the war, the Fed became the
sole fiscal agent of the Treasury, securing the deposit of all Treasury funds
at the Federal Reserve. The Morgans, exploiting its ties with England and its
position of power at the New York Fed, became the sole purchasing agent in
the U.S. for war materials to be shipped to Britain and France. The Morgans
also became the sole underwriter for British and French bonds floated in the
U.S. to pay for armaments and other goods the Allies wanted.
“Government, meanwhile, used the war as an excuse to
create what one economic historian has aptly called a ‘garrison economy.’
Among other things government took over railroads and communications
industries, seized hundreds of manufacturing plants, fixed prices, intervened
in hundreds of labor disputes, raised taxes, and conscripted a million men
for military service so they could join the bloodbath over there, in the
European trenches. The Supreme Court, the alleged guardian of the
Constitution – which itself is our alleged guardian against an aggressive
government – ruled most of the war interventions constitutional, including
the draft. Merely questioning the constitutionality of the draft could get
you thrown in jail. Thus, the federal reserve – a government-protected,
government-serving, elaborately-cloaked counterfeiting cartel – played a
crucial role in converting a peaceful America into a bellicose,
interventionist state.
“All the belligerents in the war went off the gold
standard and resorted to inflation – counterfeiting – to fund the carnage.
Taxes were raised, but only so far. Governments that attempt to fund wars by
raising taxes often find themselves facing a revolt on the home front. Wars
require massive inflation, and the institution responsible for inflation is
the government’s central bank. Without government control of the monetary
system through its central bank there would’ve been no war, or certainly not
one nearly as long or destructive.
“The war killed over 19 million people, counting both
military and civilian deaths. How many of those deaths could have been
prevented if the governments did not control the money supplies? If they had
engaged in central bank ‘disarmament’ instead of slaughtering one
another?
“Rather than pointing out the inflationary theft of
resources that underlies all modern wars, many commentators were instead
spellbound by the patriotic fervor and the wonderful command and control
economy the war brought in its wake. No doubt it was a heady experience for
the elites in command and very lucrative for a few others. In this connection
I strongly urge you to read a short book written by two-time Medal of Honor
recipient, Major General Smedley D. Butler, called War is a Racket. A racket,
General Butler said, is something that is not what it seems to the majority
of people. Only a small group of insiders knows what it is about. A racket is
conducted for the benefit of the very few at the expense of the very
many.
“We hear voices calling for patriotism during war. But who
exactly were the patriots during ‘the war to end all wars’?
"Was it J. P. Morgan, who repeatedly said, ‘Nobody
could hate war more than I do’ as he was amassing commissions totaling $30
million as a purchasing agent of war supplies for England and France?
"Was it Morgan’s steel, shipbuilding, and powder
enterprises that bought controlling interest in, and editorial control over,
the country’s 25 most influential newspapers?
"Was it President Woodrow Wilson who had won
reelection with the slogan ‘he kept us out of war’ then five months later
asked Congress to join a war that had already killed 5 million men?
"Was it Senator Robert La Follette of Wisconsin, who
rose in the Senate to dissect Wilson’s call for war point by point, arguing
that Wilson and his advisors had been colluding with Britain for two years
trying to find a pretext for American entry into the fray against England’s
enemies?
"Was it the senators who spoke after La Follette and for
five hours hotly denounced him as ‘pro-German’ and ‘anti-American’?
"Was it the majority of Americans who in spite of a
well-orchestrated media campaign against Germany still opposed joining the
war?
"Was it the million men who were conscripted and sent
overseas, over 100,000 of whom lost their lives?
"Was it the industrial firms back home, thousands of
miles from the slaughter on the Western Front, whose income tax records
showed huge profits during the war years?
"Was it the millions here who kept their mouths shut
about the war because the Espionage Act of 1917 and its successor, the
Sedition Act of 1918, hung a 20-year prison sentence over the heads of
Wilson’s critics?
“Washington, Jefferson, Madison, and John Quincy Adams are
generally considered patriotic, yet they counseled strongly against American
entanglement in foreign affairs. ‘Commerce with all nations, alliance with
none,’ were Jefferson’s famous words. America ‘well knows that by once
enlisting under other banners than her own, the fundamental maxims of her
policies would insensibly change from liberty to force,’ John Quincy Adams
warned his colleagues in a famous Fourth of July speech to Congress. ‘Of all
the enemies of true liberty,’ James Madison wrote, ‘war is, perhaps, the most
to be dreaded, because it comprises and develops the germ of every other. War
is the parent of armies; from these proceed debts and taxes; and armies, and
debts, and taxes are the known instruments for bringing the many under the
domination of the few.’
“The Fed, and its partner in theft, the income tax,
enabled politicians and their financial backers to ignore their warnings.
Should we be surprised that many American war supporters made out like
bandits? J. P. Morgan was one of those Americans who cleaned up handsomely
from the war he professed to hate. As journalist H. L. Mencken noted a few
years later, ‘The Government hospitals are now full of one-legged soldiers
who gallantly protected [Morgan’s] investments then, and the public schools
are full of boys who will protect his investments tomorrow.’
“The man who unfortunately became the most influential
inflationist of the twentieth century, John Maynard Keynes, saw clearly how
monetary fraud leads to a country’s downfall. Writing shortly after World War
I, he said, ‘There is no subtler, no surer means of overturning the existing
basis of society than to debauch the currency. The process engages all the
hidden forces of economic law on the side of destruction, and does it in a
manner which not one man in a million is able to diagnose.’ To ‘debauch’ a
currency you inflate it.
“No government bent on amassing power, however, can do so
while banknotes and deposits are still redeemable in gold. Gold, therefore,
has to go, but it must be removed in a deceptive manner, so that people won’t
notice the theft. Encouraging people to keep their gold in banks is a crucial
first step on the road to confiscation, but having it reside in local banks
means people can withdraw it easily. The next step, therefore, is to create
or exploit a crisis and cite that as an excuse to have it moved into the
vaults of the central government. In theory, it would still be accessible to
the owners, but highly inconvenient and, not coincidentally, unpatriotic to
withdraw.
“Thus, in 1917 the Federal Reserve law was changed to
allow the Fed to exchange its notes for gold, on the grounds that the
government wanted to protect the gold supply from foreigners. In dealing with
its member banks the Fed increased its holdings from 28 percent of the
nation’s gold stock before American entry into the war to 74 percent by the
war’s end. With gold largely centralized at the Fed, people were reluctant to
touch it. Instead, they dealt almost exclusively with notes that promised to
pay gold coin on demand.
“After the war, and after a depression from 1920 to 1921
made brief by government’s inability to intervene in time, the Fed continued
its inflationary policies and financed the boom years of the 1920s. Most
economists today will tell you we had no inflation during this decade because
overall prices remained the same. But the 1920s were also a period of
advancing technology and new methods of manufacturing, which improved
productivity enough to hold prices level. In other words, if the banks had
not engaged in credit expansion during the ‘20s, prices would’ve dropped, and
the country would have enjoyed prosperity without a crash waiting in the
wings. But in fact the Fed boosted the money supply by roughly $26 billion
from mid-1922 to mid-1929. And the new money pushed stock and real estate
prices up to feverish levels.
“The stock market break that began in October, 1929
signaled the beginning of a necessary correction to the preceding boom years.
From the country’s first major depression in 1819 until the depression of the
early 1920s, government had mostly allowed the economy to correct itself. The
depressions, consequently, lasted only about a year or two, and 1930 should
have been a typical period of correction and gradual recovery.
“The country’s failure to recover is unfairly blamed on
the Federal Reserve, which is charged with failing to initiate an
inflationary binge to restore the lost euphoria. The Fed certainly tried to
inflate the economy back to the boom by lowering interest rates and
purchasing government securities, and it deserves blame for the Crash itself
because of the money it created. But it was government intervention that
deepened and prolonged the depression.
“To repeat, credit expansion brought on the Crash,
government policies lengthened and intensified the depression.
“On the surface, the goals of the interventionists had a
noble ring – they were being done to keep wage rates and prices from falling.
Thus, for example, the Hawley-Smoot Tariff of June, 1930 was promoted as a
way to support domestic industry and labor, but it virtually closed foreign
markets to American products. Agriculture, a major export industry, was hit
particularly hard, and prices for farm products dropped to unprecedented
lows. Hundreds of thousands of farmers went into bankruptcy, and the rural
banks who were their creditors suffered the consequences. From 1930 to 1933,
many thousands of banks failed. The crushing blow to agriculture caused great
harm to the banking system, which in turn spread panic to its millions of
customers.
“The Hoover administration did everything it could to
revive the economy, which was precisely why economic conditions grew worse.
They believed the command economy installed for World War I had been
effective in putting the U.S. on the winning side. If government controls
were successful during a war, why not put government in charge of a receding
economy? Having abandoned the teachings of the classical liberals, they
believed that government decrees had produced the goods that won the war.
Another round of government impositions, they were convinced, would again
make the desired outcome appear.
“‘We could have done nothing,’ Hoover said during his 1932
presidential campaign, but ‘that would have been utter ruin.’ He attacked
those economists who had urged a hands-off approach, claiming he was
determined not to ‘follow the advice of the bitter-end liquidationists ,‘ as
he disparagingly called them, and see the whole body of debtors and savers
‘brought to destruction.’
“But he only intensified the destruction he sought to
avoid. Liquidation of unsound projects created by the inflationary boom was
precisely the tonic needed to revive the economy, as history and theory had
made clear. When he left office, his coercive concern for the whole body of
debtors and savers left one in four workers unemployed, a new low in American
history.
“And yet, incredibly, we find historians and economists
describing Hoover’s policies as ‘laissez-faire,’ as if he sat back and did
nothing while the economy tried to correct itself. If only he had. He
intervened far more than any president before him and brought the economy to
its knees. Government should ‘do something’ was the dominant thinking then as
now, and applying the laissez-faire label pinned the blame on the market
instead of the government. If Hoover had been re-elected, he might have been
even more aggressive in attacking the economy. As it was, he left that to his
successor.
“In his inaugural address the new U.S. president told the
American people their economic problems were due to ‘unscrupulous money
changers’ whose conduct in banking and business was ‘callous’ and ‘selfish.’
He promised his listeners that if Congress should fail to act properly, he
would ask them for broad executive powers that might be given to a president
in the event of an invasion. One Supreme Court justice described the
depression as ‘an emergency more serious than war.’ Taking the hint, Congress
acceded to the president’s wish and granted him dictatorial powers to resolve
the banking crisis.
“After his inaugural address Roosevelt issued Presidential
Proclamation 2039 in which he explained the cause of the national emergency
as the ‘heavy and unwarranted withdrawals of gold and currency from our
banking institutions for the purpose of hoarding,’ along with speculation
abroad in foreign exchange that ‘has resulted in severe drains on the
Nation’s stocks of gold.’ Gold and hoarding were his targets. ‘It is in the best
interests of all bank depositors,’ he concluded, ‘that a period of respite be
provided’ to prevent ‘further hoarding of coin, bullion or currency or
speculation in foreign exchange.’ He concluded the proclamation by closing
all banks in 1933 from March 6 to March 9, inclusive.
“Hoarding is a pejorative term for an increase in an
individual’s cash holdings. If hoarders are guilty of anything, it’s for
exposing the unscrupulous and unsound nature of the banking system for
manufacturing multiple claims to the same deposit of gold. In 1931, as people
were redeeming $800 million in bank deposits for cash, Hoover lashed out at
them for their ‘traitorous hoarding.’ In early 1932 he organized a citizens
committee and launched a public campaign against hoarders, blaming them for
keeping the country mired in the depression by withholding money from
circulation. Evidently, Roosevelt and his Brain Trust agreed with him. But
people, in taking their money out of the banks, were only trying to protect
what was rightfully theirs. There would have been no problems with hoarding
had the bankers not been cheating them.
“We need to remember that money is a medium of exchange
and not wealth as such, and the act of withdrawing deposits and keeping them
off the market, which decreases the money supply, does not destroy wealth. It
only means each monetary unit will command more resources than before. In
other words, prices will drop.
“But as we saw, falling prices and wages had been the
devil government was fighting. Government spokesmen had reversed cause and
effect – at least in their public statements. Rather than seeing the
depression as causing prices and wages to drop, they credulously proclaimed
that lower prices and wages caused the depression, ignoring ample historical
evidence to the contrary. By their logic, therefore, bringing the country out
of the depression was a matter of boosting prices and wages to where they
were during the good times before the Crash. Since ‘hoarding’ was keeping
this from happening, on April 5, 1933 Roosevelt ordered all people with gold
in their possession to turn it over to the Federal Reserve, for which they
would receive government paper money in return.
"Who could pass up a deal like that? The government
figured everyone could, so they made it a felony for failing to comply,
punishable by a fine not exceeding $10,000 and a prison sentence of up to 10
years.
“In its eagerness to inflate the money supply, government
was busy inflating the criminal supply. People, in other words, were becoming
criminals only because they were resisting the criminality of the state. One
of our foremost economic commentators cites the famous work of Friedman and
Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960, in
pointing out that many American citizens anticipated Roosevelt’s gold
confiscation and successfully kept their property from the state’s greedy
hands. During the three months prior to Roosevelt’s gold grab, circulating
gold coin diminished by a whopping 35.5 percent. The state’s actual theft was
only 3.9 million ounces or 22 percent of the gold coin then in circulation.
Friedman and Schwartz conclude that the remaining 78 percent – roughly 13.9
million ounces of gold – “was retained illegally in private hands.” I commend
those people who resisted the plunder, whoever they were.
“If it had been possible to print gold, government would
never have abandoned the gold standard. But it did, and the alleged evil
preventing recovery was eliminated by presidential decree. Government now had
a money machine with virtually no brakes. They could inflate the money supply
as necessary, drive prices and wages up, and put people back to work.
“Things didn’t go exactly as planned and another World War
had to start – and end – before the economy returned to its pre-Crash
condition."
|
|