The financial instability that first surfaced
with full force in 2008 is the result of a deteriorating condition in world
finance going back 40 years. Worse still, that deterioration is continuing
and threatens with an historically unprecedented world-wide credit collapse.
The
watershed year was 1971. What made that year outstanding was not just the
first-ever introduction of the world-wide floating exchange rate system, but
also the disappearance of the most potent and reliable financial instrument
that has ever existed. It was little noticed at the time. If ever mentioned,
it was being treated as a non-event. Yet the world can only dismiss its
significance at its own peril. Academia that is supposed to study problems
created by monetary experimentation, rather than alerting the public to the
most serious consequences of the omission, has been guilty of ignoring it.
The
most potent financial instrument, the disappearance of which we are referring
to, is the gold bond.
This
observation would immediately be objected to by the detractors of gold in the
monetary system. They would say that the gold bond had disappeared from world
finance much earlier: in the years 1931-35. Its disappearance gave no
occasion for any major catastrophe in its wake. Rather, the word economy has
gone on from one triumph to another without gold bonds ever since ¾
proving the inconsequential nature of their being phased out. However, this
objection is not valid.
The
truth of the matter is that the gold bond had survived the collapse of the
gold standard in the early 1930’s and has played a most important
albeit largely unrecognized role in world finance afterwards. Consider the
fact that since January, 1934, the dollar has had a fixed value in terms of gold,
based on the Treasury price of $35 per ounce of fine gold, and the U.S.
government has continued to honor its international dollar obligations in
gold at that rate. Moreover, this obligation was solemnly enshrined in
several international treaties and confirmed by four sitting presidents. As a
result, there is no gainsaying of the fact that U.S. Treasury paper in the
hands of foreign governments and central banks directly, and in the hands of
banks, financial institutions, and even ordinary citizens not under the
jurisdiction of the U.S. indirectly, have continued to exist as gold bonds
(or gold bills, as the case may be) after 1934.
The
most important role the gold bond has played up until 1971 was this: it was
the standard of credit whereby all other debt instruments were gaged. Through
disintermediation substandard debt was eliminated, and the rise of the Debt
Behemoth prevented.
Ignoring this fact is a major error that
Academia has been and still is making. To continue to deny this fact leads to
further grievous errors. There used to be a saying on Lombard Street, long
since forgotten, that “there is only one thing that is safer and
arguably more desirable to hold than gold, namely, the promise of a
government to pay gold”. In that spirit gold bonds were considered
an “ultimate form of debt”, enforcing quality standards.
Moreover, the U.S. Treasury bill in the hands of foreigners was, along with
gold, the ultimate extinguisher of debt. This instrument was destroyed
on August 15, 1971. On that day gold was exiled from the international
monetary system. Since that day the world has lacked an ultimate extinguisher
of debt.
Any other means of payment, including Federal
Reserve credit, however useful in international trade or otherwise, could not
extinguish debt. It could only shift debt from one debtor to another
(ultimately, to the U.S. government). As long as there were gold bonds in
existence, a Debt Behemoth could not rise to threaten world finance with
destruction. Whenever total debt in the world approached the danger level,
safety-conscious governments and banks quietly started converting their
holdings of debt into gold bonds, thus squeezing marginal debt out of
existence. This also explains the absence of a derivative tower and other
unsafe financial constructions, instruments and practices, such as
mortgage-based bonds, or bank-loan-backed bonds, prior to 1971.
World trade was financed and regulated by gold
to the extent that the great trading houses abroad kept a portfolio of gold
bonds in their balance sheet. In effect they were doing arbitrage between the
gold bond market and the market for internationally traded merchandise. If
the gold rate of interest (the yield of U.S. Treasury bonds) rose, they sold
out marginal merchandise from warehouses without reordering them, and
invested the proceeds in gold bonds. If subsequently the gold rate of
interest rates fell back, then they would sell the gold bond at a profit, and
invest the proceeds in marginal merchandise, the trading of which out of the
warehouse yielded better profit than that available from holding the gold
bond. This arbitrage was real, continuous, and it kept international trade on
an even keel. Academia has missed this important arbitrage responsible for
regulating world trade after World War II. It has also been guilty of failing
to point out that, without gold bonds, world trade is clueless, subject to
deterioration and open to manipulation.
In
1971, by a stroke of the pen, gold bonds were stamped out of existence. World
trade lost its guiding star. The floodgates of exorbitant debt creation were
opened. The fast debt-breeder was turned on. Debt of dubious quality flooded
the word, the soundness of which could no longer be
gaged in the absence of gold bonds. There was no sink to absorb excess and
waste. This explains the origin of the debt tower, and the steady
deterioration of the quality of its component parts. This process is still
continuing. Worst of all, the series of financial crises in the world also
continues. Every one of them will be more devastating than the preceding one
— unless something is done about it, and soon. In the absence of
remedial measures now the momentum of the approaching avalanche will become
overwhelming.
Remedies
Having made the correct diagnosis, the remedy readily presents
itself. The gold bond should be brought back. There is presently a
great latent demand for gold bonds in the world, as indicated by the high
marketability U.S. Treasury bonds are still enjoying — something that
cannot be justified on purely economic grounds in view of the net debt of the
U.S. government and the tenaciousness of the American trade and budget
deficits. Make no mistake about it: the high marketability of the U.S.
Treasury bonds is justified solely by the fact that there is still a residual
hope that the U.S. government will, in its own self-interest as well as in
the interest of the world economy, make them payable in gold at maturity, and
will pay interest on them in gold in the meantime.
Most significantly, there is a convincing
precedent in U.S. history for this. During the Civil War and its aftermath,
the U.S. government continued to honor its debt, both as to principal and
interest, paying them in the gold coin of the realm. To be able to do it, the
government continued to levy import duties and excise taxes in gold to the exclusion of paper. The exchange rate between the gold
dollar and the paper dollar (endearingly called the ‘greenback’
by their protagonists) was fluctuating. The government need not embrace a
gold standard in order to enjoy the benefits offered by the gold bond.
There
is no reason why the U.S. could not emulate the Civil War practice in the
present crisis. Admittedly, it would take extensive research to work out the
details. For example, the question arises how gold bonds can survive in a
fiat paper money system (or how a fiat paper money system can prosper in an
environment where gold bonds exist and enjoy the highest prestige). At any
rate, the intellectual resources to conduct such research are all at hand. If
not residing in Academia, then, at least, they are scattered around in small
discussion groups and can be accessed through the Internet. There ought to be
such a thing as “shadow research” offering sorely missed
competition to mainstream economics on the gold question.
The
first obstacle that confronts the present effort by the U.S. government and
the Fed to put the great financial crisis behind them is that it runs head on
into Triffin’s Dilemma. Already in the early 1960’s Robert
Triffin observed that the stated aims of increasing ‘world
liquidity’ and those of eliminating the U.S. budget deficit are
contradictory. They cannot be simultaneously accomplished.
Likewise, the present effort to rein in the U.S. government
deficit and reduce the outstanding government debt, while simultaneously
increasing the stock of money through direct sales of government bonds by the
Treasury to the Fed (euphemistically called QE 1 & 2) are contradictory.
It is like trying to have one’s cake and eat it. On the one hand the
Fed wants to inject more Federal Reserve credit into the payments system while the “other hand”, the government, pretends to
choke off the supply of the necessary collateral through eliminating the
budget deficit. Politicians, mainstream economists and financial journalists
sing the praise of this scheme without realizing that it cannot be done. The
two aims are contradictory, and the market will not be fooled by the
prestidigitation.
Most mainstream economists have a
vested interest in maintaining their anti-gold stance. Their prestige is
committed to Keynes’ dictum that the gold standard (and, by
implication, gold) is nothing but a ‘barbarous
relic’. However, if they really believe in a goldless monetary system,
then they should have nothing to fear in exposing their fiat paper scheme to
competition with the gold bond. Hand-to-hand money will still be irredeemable
under the suggested remedial action. The fact that this will cause the
managers of fiat money to make their instrument deliver stellar performance
so that people shall have no desire to dump paper in favor of gold is an
added benefit. The remedial action proposed here ought not to be seen as an
attempt to return to the gold standard through the back door. The proposal is
to allow the gold bond to discharge its natural function, to wit: weeding out
bad debt something irredeemable debt cannot do.
A
great failing of monetary scholarship is the one-sided appraisal of the
origin and subsequent evolution of the Federal Reserve System that came about
as a result of six years of thorough study and public debate in the wake of
the 1907 financial panic. It was not even remotely considered during the
debate that the Fed coming off the drawing board ought to be an engine
monetizing government debt. Just the opposite is true: the Fed was supposed
to be a commercial paper system whereby self-liquidating bills of exchange
would acquire ephemeral monetary privileges, facilitating the movement of
semi-finished merchandise from the producer to the ultimate consumer. This
was not considered inflationary: pari passu with the sale of
merchandise to the ultimate consumer the expiring
bills diminish the money supply dollar for dollar.
Nor
was it thought possible during the debate that the monetary unit of the
United States could be anything but the Constitutional double eagle gold
coin. There was nothing sinister about the study and the debate. There was no
conspiracy. It was all in the open. All questions could be openly asked and
would be honestly answered.
The
outcome, the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 was far from being a perfect
document. It had many weak points, errors of commission as well as errors of
omission. It had a lot of room for improvement. But it was acceptable for the
purpose of putting credit, such as existed within the confines of the United
States, on a sound and enduring financial basis.
Mischief
occurred after the Federal Reserve banks opened their door for
business in 1914, about the same time when the war in Europe got started.
Without much thinking, and in an obvious violation of the law and the
neutrality of the country, the Administration of president Wilson committed
the new Federal Reserve banks to the task of financing of the allied war
effort in Europe. The idea of self-liquidating credit was discarded; credit
was created expressly to finance destruction. You could not get further away
from the ideal of self-liquidating credit than putting credit in the service
of destroying life and property.
This
takes us to the second remedy: restoration of self-liquidating credit.
The idea that the central bank can calibrate the rate of debasement of the
currency by adjusting the speed of the printing press is absurd. It is only
surpassed by the absurdity of the notion that the Federal Open Market
Committee can divine, pick, and set the optimal interest rate that will make
the GDP grow, payrolls swell, prices stabilize, and prosperity endure.
Historically,
commercial banks came into existence not to ‘create’ credit but
to ‘liquefy’ it. Commercial credit takes its origin in the
handshake of two businessmen while one saying to the other: “I’ll
pay you for this shipment in 90 days”. The handshake later took the
form of a real bill. It had the advantage that it could be endorsed and
passed on to a third party in payment for other merchandise.
Thus
the formula to solve the present crisis of instability, and to fend off the
threatening credit collapse is: Go back to gold bonds and real bills. Adopt
the best agents of credit there obtain, in place of intrinsically worthless
promises. Substitute the real source of credit, the handshake of two
businessmen, for the stroke of the banker’s pen.
The
hour is late. At stake is the survival of the U.S. and the world economy as
we know it. Failure to act now would lead to a disaster comparable only to
the collapse of the Roman Empire in the fifth century A.D. that was
accompanied with a total breakdown of law and order while, significantly
enough, gold was going into hiding.
Antal E. Fekete
Copyright
© 2002-2008 by Antal E. Fekete - All rights reserved
|