|
(This item originally appeared at Forbes.com on February 16, 2012.)
http://www.forbes.com/sites/nathanlewis/2012/...t-money-growth/
Among the silliest things that people say about gold standard systems is that
under them, the “money supply” grows about 2% per year, due to mining. This
is demonstrably false – not only that, but so utterly wrong as to induce
falling-off-the-chair guffaws from those who understand such things.
Doesn’t anyone know how to play this game?
I like to take the example of the United States. In 1775, the total amount of
currency in circulation (primarily gold and silver coins) was an estimated
$12 million. In 1900, it was $1,954 million target="_blank"– an
increase of 163x!
During this time period, the amount of gold in the world increased by about
3.4 times, due to mining production.
Obviously, the two have nothing at all to do with one another. If you were to
take similar statistics, from Italy or Britain or France or Germany, you
would find that the growth of the money supply in those countries was
completely different than that of the U.S., although all of them used a gold
standard system.
For example, between 1880 and 1900, the monetary base in Italy actually target="_blank" shrank by
4.8%. However, the monetary base in the U.S. target="_blank" grew by 81%
over those same years. Both used gold standard systems. So, the “money supply”
not only has no relation to gold mining production, but two countries can
have wildly different outcomes during the same time period.
The value of the dollar was about the same in 1775 and 1900, approximately
$20 per ounce of gold (or a dollar worth 1/20th ounce of gold).
So, what’s going on here? The important thing about gold, as a basis for
monetary systems, is that its value is stable. Certainly, one important
reason why its value is stable is that the quantity of it in the world
doesn’t change much – only about 2% per year. Unlike virtually all other
commodities, the amount of gold in inventory is vastly in excess of its
annual production. This makes gold singularl target="_blank"y
insensitive to variations in supply.
However, a gold standard system can make available any amount of currency, as
is appropriate given economic needs and the fixed parity value. Just as the
U.S. economy grew enormously in the 1775-1900 period, the gold standard
system allowed the money supply to also grow enormously, as was appropriate
at the time.
Previously, we looked at exactly how this could work, with target="_blank" an example
of a very simple 100% reserve, bullion warehouse receipt-type system,
hypothetically applied to Belize. target="_blank" Here
you can see how the gold standard system can expand and shrink the money
supply as appropriate, as part of the mechanism that maintains the value of
the currency at its parity rate.
Unfortunately, some gold standard advocates have been somewhat devoted to
this “money supply growing at 2% a year” stuff. Naturally, their critics, the
academic Keynesians, are quick to note that an economy might need more than
2% year money supply growth, as the U.S. economy did in the 19th century.
Alas, the gold standard advocates have painted a big “kick me” sign on their back.
What do you think is going to happen next?
Actually, these discussions date from quite a while back. What’s really at
issue here is not the ability of a gold standard system to expand and
accommodate a growing economy if necessary. Obviously the money supply grew a
very large amount in the U.S. during the 19th century, and obviously the gold
standard system did not hold back economic development. The United States was
the greatest economic development story of that century. When you want to
make an example of failure, you usually don’t choose the reigning World
Champion.
Rather, this was something of a rhetorical trick of the devaluationists, who
have been around long before John Maynard Keynes was born. In the 1896
presidential election (Keynes was thirteen years old at the time), the
Democratic Party wanted to devalue the dollar by about 50% in the form of
“free coinage of silver.” Devaluationists have always been around, but they
didn’t have the upper hand in those days. The Republicans won that election,
and the U.S. remained on the gold standard.
“Devaluation” has always been a dirty word. Almost always, the
devaluationists hide their goals behind some other rhetorical curtain,
whether it be “free coinage of silver” or “lower interest rates” or “let
market forces decide” or whatever is politically expedient at the time.
Whenever there is some sort of recessionary event, the devaluationists will
argue that things would be better off with some sort of “easy money” policy.
These “easy money” policies lead directly to currency decline and a floating
currency, which the gold standard prevents. Thus, the devaluationists
immediately argue that the gold standard system is preventing the “growth of
the economy” that would supposedly happen as a result of the “easy money”
policy. This has nothing to do with the gold standard system itself, which is
wholly capable of accommodating the increased demand for money that usually
accompanies economic expansion. It is just a rhetorical device of the
devaluationists.
With that said, the 19th century did have some periods when the intent to
reinstate a gold standard system, after a currency devaluation, resulted in a
rising currency, with some recessionary effects. This was especially true in
the 1865-1879 period in the U.S., and to a lesser extent around 1816-1819.
This effect was not caused by the gold standard system itself, but rather
from the decisions made as to how to return to a gold standard system after a
period of floating currencies.
Given that we in the United States had 182 years of direct experience with
gold standard systems, from 1789 to 1971, you would think people would
understand these things a little better. On the bright side, as the Keynesian
floating currency experiment fails a little more each year, the pace of new
understanding has improved considerably.
|
|