|
We have been examining the ideas of the
Neo-Keynesians recently, so, in the interest of equal opportunity, we will
now examine the ideas of the Rothbardians.
First: what is a Rothbardian?
That is my name for a group loosely allied with the ideas of Murray Rothbard. Murray Rothbard was a
student of the 19th century classicalists, of which the last
surviving member (in my opinion) was Ludwig Von Mises.
Rothbard later morphed these old ideas into new
forms, which is fine of course, and the natural process of intellectual
evolution. But, it would be nice to have forward evolution, i.e.,
improvement, rather than reverse evolution, or devolution! Keynes likewise
was a student of the 19th century classicalists in his youth, and,
like Rothbard, morphed these ideas into his own
sorts of new forms.
I call them "Rothbardians"
to distinguish them from the "Austrians," which is sort of a
catch-all phrase describing the later-period 19th century
classicalists. They themselves would call themselves "Austrians."
Exactly like Keynes, Rothbard
was motivated to undertake this "evolution" in response to the
Great Depression of the 1930s. On top of this lies another long-standing
political issue, that of the Federal Reserve and other such central banks,
with the Fed signed into law in 1913. The Keynesians, who are really
Mercantilists in drag, tend to favor active
monetary manipulation, just as the original Mercantilists did in the 17th
and early 18th century. The Classicalists, beginning with John
Locke at the very end of the 18th century, favored
a stable bullion-based currency free of government manipulation. The
Classicalists carried the day, of course, until the 1930s, when
Keynesian/Mercantilist ideas swung back to the forefront.
The original Keynesians, of the 1930s, like
many others of the time, saw the Great Depression as being caused by a sort
of negative feedback loop touched off by the stock market decline of late
1929. The stock market decline caused a mood of "caution," thus
reducing the "propensity to consume," thus reducing the revenues of
businesspeople, leading to reduced capital expenditures and layoffs, thus
leading to a further reductions in consumption, thus spiraling
downward. Capitalism was fragile! The government must step in to save
capitalism from itself! The way in which the government would step in,
according to Keynes, was to spend money on public works projects and play
games with the monetary system. The means by which the Keynesians would play
games with money was the Federal Reserve, which was created for an entirely
different purpose two decades earlier.
Today, we can see that the stock market
decline of 1929 didn't just happen out of nowhere, but was almost certainly
caused by the fact that a majority in Congress that opposed the gigantic
Smoot-Hawley Tariff, was changed to a majority in favor.
On that very day, the stock market plunged, as foreign governments had
already made clear that the Smoot-Hawley tariff would lead to very harsh
retaliatory tariffs worldwide. Tariffs did indeed explode higher around the
world in 1930 as the Smoot-Hawley Tariff was signed, with worldwide recession
the result that year. This recession did not spiral down in a "negative
feedback loop" into Depression all by itself, but was forced in that
direction by an absolute explosion of domestic taxes worldwide, as
governments sought to counter the falloff in tax revenue caused by the
tariff-induced recession with enormous increases in tax rates. As noted, the
US government eventually raised its top income tax rate from 24% to 63%.
Which was a real smart thing to do in the middle of a Depression.
Now let's go forward to 1962, the year of
publication not only of Rothbard's book America's
Great Depression but also of Milton Friedman's Monetary History of the
United States. After thirty years of Neo-Mercantilism (i.e. old-style
Keynesianism), the Classicalists began to muster an intellectual response.
Friedman embraced the Mercantilist/Keynesian principle of monetary
manipulation (by the Fed) wholeheartedly. Rothbard
did not, hewing instead (vaguely) to the Classicalists' principle of stable,
neutral, bullion-based money. In addition, since the Keynesians and the
Monetarists both saw the Fed (created for a wholly different purpose in 1913)
as the tool by which they would carry out their economic and monetary
manipulation, the Fed became the focus of Rothbard's
criticism. Indeed, the Fed had been a target of criticism of the
Classicalists since its creation, as it is a privately-owned institution
whose effective monopoly on money-printing is wildly profitable (about $35B
per year these days, paid by U.S. taxpayers) -- this likely going into the
pockets of some rather shady characters based in London. Thus, Rothbard had two motivations to "fight the
Fed."
So is it any surprise that Rothbard's
1962 book blames the Great Depression on the Fed? Not really -- even though Rothbard spends most of the book delineating quite
precisely the tax hikes worldwide that did so much to crumple the world
economy. Ignoring this, however, his basic hypothesis is that the Fed
"inflated the money supply" in the 1920s (the U.S. was on the gold
standard at the time), creating a "bubble in the stock market" (in
September 1929 it was trading at 13x forward earnings estimates), and then,
borrowing a bit from the Keynesians, the collapse of the bursting bubble
caused a negative-feedback-loop downward spiral into Depression. This sort of
rhetoric is all-too-common today, alas, producing all sorts of sloppy
analysis about the present situation. Thus, politically, the Rothbardians have defined themselves as being anti-Fed,
while the Keynesians and Monetarists are pro-Fed, both using the Great Depression
as justification for their arguments, although the history of that period
supports neither!
The U.S. of the 1920s was on a gold standard.
Indeed, the U.S. was on a gold standard in the 1930s, the 1940s, the 1950s
and 1960s as well, albeit one with occasional challenges, aberrations and
difficulties. The Keynesians and Monetarists, both seeing the Fed as their
tool of economic manipulation, thus became enemies of the gold standard, as
the gold standard prevented the Fed from doing anything of any great
significance -- just as the gold standard prevented the Fed from doing
anything of great significance in the 1920s and 1930s. The Rothbardians also chose to ignore that this gold standard
even existed, as they were convinced that the Fed was allowed, in the 1920s,
to create an "inflationary bubble" of the most destructive
proportions. The Rothbardians' blaming of the Great
Depression on the Fed, by implication, puts blame on the gold standard of the
1920s-1960s as being ineffective in countering such imaginary manipulation.
This led the Rothbardians to adopt the most bizarre
notions of what constitutes a gold standard, which they call the
"pure" or "true" or "100%" gold standard. This
is most odd, since Rothbard actually lived during
the period of the Bretton Woods gold standard,
which, despite its many flaws and enemies, worked pretty well.
In the 1970s, when it was clear that leaving
the gold standard in 1971 was a bad idea, it would have been a simple matter
to say: "maybe we should go back to something like Bretton
Woods." But instead, the Rothbardians,
following their "100% gold standard" ideas, were telling everyone
that banking should be illegal. You can imagine how well that went over:
"The economy is falling apart, and we think the solution is to make
banking illegal." Sounds like Fidel Castro!
The Rothbardians
haven't been making as much noise about the "100%" gold standard
lately, as perhaps they have quietly concluded that it is an embarrassment.
This is a most wonderful development, as finally, the various
"classical" economic thinkers are beginning to see how gold
standards actually work, how they have always worked, and how one could be
implemented in practice. A most opportune time, as well, since it appears the
Neo-Keynesians, like our Fed Chairman Bernanke, are about to puke on their
shoes again, to the general detriment of the world economy.
It sure would be nice if the good guys in this
drama, the classicalists, don't try to pull that "let's make banking
illegal" stuff again. If they do, they would all be branded with the
Scarlet K (for "kooks"), and we would all have to suffer from the
mistakes of the Neo-Keynesians for another generation or two.
Nathan
Lewis
Nathan Lewis was formerly the chief international
economist of a leading economic forecasting firm. He now works in asset
management. Lewis has written for the Financial Times, the Wall Street
Journal Asia, the Japan Times, Pravda, and other publications. He has
appeared on financial television in the United
States, Japan,
and the Middle East. About the Book: Gold:
The Once and Future Money (Wiley, 2007, ISBN: 978-0-470-04766-8, $27.95) is
available at bookstores nationwide, from all major online booksellers, and
direct from the publisher at www.wileyfinance.com or 800-225-5945. In Canada,
call 800-567-4797.
|
|