This article
takes up where the first part
left off: the dismantling of the London Gold Pool in March 1968. The US
authority's fight to keep gold pegged at $35 had by no means ended with the
Pool's demise. Instead it shifted to a new front. That same month a massive
gold embargo against South Africa, the world's largest gold producer, was
initiated by the US, a battle that would last till early 1970.
The US led
embargo against South Africa , backed implicitly by the largest military in
the world, highlights the gradual but steady tendency for authorities to back
the failing $35 peg by forceful means. This is the inevitable route taken by
any state-run financial system experiencing difficulty. Whereas in a free
banking system mistakes are fixed through market discipline, competition, and
failures, the state's mistakes in banking are maintained as long as its
monopoly on force can keep these mistakes from destroying the system.
To recap, the
Bretton Woods Agreement negotiated after World War II set the value of the
dollar at 0.81 grams. This value was backed by the United States Federal
Reserve's promise to convert all dollars into gold at the stipulated ratio of
0.81 grams, the more well known ratio being $35 dollars to one ounce. This
promise was further enhanced by the fact that the Fed held some 21,000 tonnes
of the metal, more gold than all other central banks combined. Dollar's
convertibility was limited to foreign governments and central banks —
private citizens in both the US and overseas who owned dollars held what was
essentially inconvertible paper money.
Bretton Woods
vs. Free Banking
To understand
this system, it helps to compare it to a hypothetical world of private banks
issuing currency in a free market. In such a system, the option that currency
holders have to exercise gold convertibility forces discipline on individual
banks. A bank that issues more of its branded money than the market is willing
to support, say by lowering its own interest rate on loans below the market's
rate, will soon face a wave of its own currency returning to it for
conversion. The irresponsible bank's gold reserves will decline and it will
be forced to call in loans to rebuild reserves, or increase interest rates
back to at least the market rate to attract gold deposits.
In a free
banking system, customers are free to choose the notes of whatever banks
offer the most reserves to back up their issue, further disciplining banks
that might wish to expand beyond a reserve ratio that customers prefer. At
the extreme, transgressing banks are punished by run which may lead to bank
failure. In that case, remaining assets are taken over by competitors,
restoring balance to the system.
The US Federal
Reserve operating under Bretton Woods was by no means exempt from the same
pressures that individual banks in a free banking system would be subject to.
As my first article pointed out, a massive US balance of payments deficit
began to appear in the 1950s, driven in part by government spending overseas
including military expenditures and foreign aid to a rebuilding Europe. To
fund these expenditures, the Federal government issued bonds which were
bought by the Fed with newly printed dollars. By 1951 the Fed held more
treasury bonds on it's balance sheet than gold.
As happens in a
free banking system, once the mass of dollars created by the Fed exceeded
demand they began to be returned to the US for conversion into gold by
foreign central banks. This process began in earnest in 1958, when US
reserves plummeted by 9%. A free bank would have been forced by competitive
forces to reduce money creation, call in loans, increase interest rates, and
rebuild reserves. Here is where the comparison between the Fed under Bretton
Woods and free banks end, because the Fed and its partner the US government
have one other policy option that the free banks don't; they can resort to
their monopoly on force.
Thus began the
constantly escalating attempts through the 1950s and 60s to prevent the same
market forces that exercise discipline on free banks from exercising
discipline on the US. The monetary authority's goal was to forcibly stem the
flow of US dollars overseas, reduce the gold price, and plug the rising
number of conversion claims for dollars to gold on the part of foreign
governments.
For instance,
in 1959 Eisenhower made it illegal for Americans to buy gold overseas —
extending Roosevelt's 1933 ban on American domestic holdings of gold. In 1964
a new tax was imposed by President Kennedy on foreign currency deposits to
prevent Americans from investing overseas — the Interest Equalization
Tax. In August 1970 President Nixon was given discretionary authority to
impose wage and price controls on citizens.
Soft nanny
state campaigns by the state to discourage tourism and therefore dollar
outflows, including Lyndon B Johnson's comments that "We may have to
forego the pleasures of Europe for a while,"[1] and "I am asking the American people to defer
for the next two years all non-essential travel outside the western
hemisphere," became common. In 1968 Johnson would also forbid all
American investment in Europe and impose limits on investments elsewhere.
All this is
terribly ironic as Kennedy, Johnson, and Nixon were clamping down on American
economic freedoms at the same time that they were waging a war of aggression
in Vietnam. By forcing the American public to spend less overseas, Kennedy
and Johnson realized they would free up more room for their own overseas
campaigns.
There are
umpteen examples of forceful means being used to reduce the freedom of
individuals in order to save the $35 peg from that era. One by one they
failed, including the London Gold Pool, only to be replaced by even stronger
forms of coercion. The last and probably the most overtly aggressive of these
was the South Africa embargo.
The Embargo of
1968-69
Leaving off
from the last article, central banks asked for the London gold market to be
closed and dismantled the gold pool on March 15, 1968. Without price
suppression from pool sales, the market price of gold immediately vaulted to
$39 upon the market's reopening. That same day, in what became to be called
the Washington accord, western central banks led by US Treasury Secretary
Robert Fowler announced that the world's monetary reserves were
"sufficient" and no subsequent purchases or sales by central banks
in any market would be necessary.
This last
seemingly innocuous statement had large repercussions. If central banks
ceased buying gold, monetary demand for the metal would dry-up. South Africa,
producer of some 75% of the world's gold, would suddenly find no outlet for a
bulk of its new gold. After all, the lion's share of world gold demand was by
central banks.
Fowler hoped
that the boycott would force South Africa to funnel gold sales into the
relatively small London market, dominated by jewellers, speculators, and
other private parties, depressing the market price from $39 back to the
official one at $35. This amounted to substituting the London gold pool,
active from 1961-68, and its dampening influence on the gold price, with
South African sales, the latter without South Africa 's permission. Letters
were sent to 95 central banks asking them to desist from all gold purchases.[2] The boycott had started.
South Africa
Gains the Upper Hand
From the
beginning the boycott was a failure. Rather than falling the gold price
steadily rose from $38 to $42. The 20% price differential between the official
price of $35 and the market price put a mockery to the whole managed Bretton
Woods system. In essence, the market was saying it didn't believe that the US
dollar was worth the gold value that the authorities claimed. Rather than a
dollar being convertible into 0.81 grams, the market was betting that, once
the chips were down, the dollar was likely only convertible into just 0.67
grams.
At the same
time, the price differential provided a tremendous arbitrage opportunity to
central banks. To make an easy profit, all they had to do was bring their
dollars to the Federal Reserve, convert them to gold at $35, ship their horde
to London, and sell it for $42, further exacerbating the US's already
significant gold outflows.
Despite the
pressure on South Africa to sell in London, the London gold price never
caved. Rather than selling gold on the market, the Reserve Bank of South
Africa skirted the boycott by purchasing the gold produced by mining firms
and hoarding it. By the end of 1968, South African gold reserves at the
central bank had doubled from an opening balance of about $600 million to
$1.2 billion.[3]
While this kept
gold off the London market and prices high, it meant that the nation could no
longer send its main export product overseas to pay for imports. Luckily,
South Africa had been running a significant capital account surplus since
early 1965. World equity markets had been rising since the last bear market
bottomed in 1966. Foreign investors, bullish on South Africa, were flooding
South Africa with foreign currency, and for the time being there was no need
to sell gold.
The boycott
amounted to a game of chicken between the US and South Africa. At some point
the flow of investment capital into South Africa could dry up and the
nation's gold reserves would have to be sold in the open market to fund
imports. But before that, the differential between gold's market price and
the official price could stretch even wider, weakening the resolve of the
participants in the American led boycott to the point where central banks, in
particular those in Europe, might start buying gold again.
Many South
Africans hoped to see an official devaluation of the dollar, i.e., a rise in
the official price of gold, South Africa's main source of income. With the
market price of gold at $42, arbitrage profits might get so tempting that the
world's central banks would converge on the US en masse to convert dollars to
gold. US reserves would plummet, and a devaluation would be forced. In this
game of chicken, it was a question of what happened first: South Africa being
forced to sell its gold or a run on the US forcing it to give up $35 gold.
South Africa
actively tried to sell some of its hoard by targeting potential boycott
breakers with cheap gold prices. Portugal broke the blockade in late 1968
when its central bank bought some $150 million in gold from South Africa.
They would buy another $120 million in 1969.[4] Rumours persisted that other European central banks
had crossed the picket line too.
The
International Monetary Fund was also a potential sop for South African gold.
IMF rules stipulated that the fund was required to buy all gold offered up to
it by members. This, at least, was the opinion of IMF head Pierre-Paul
Schweitzer and most IMF officials.[5] Treasury Secretary Fowler held the rather
convenient opinion that the IMF had no obligation to buy anyone's gold, in
particular South Africa's.
Rather than
accepting a South African request to buy 1 million ounces of gold in May
1968, the IMF board of directors deferred any decision on the legality of
gold purchases, thereby giving South Africa the cold shoulder[6]. The US, with 25% of board votes, had no small part
in determining this policy. This closed yet another avenue for South African
gold.
Through most of
1968 South Africa would funnel small tester sales into the London market to
determine the resiliency of prices. Prices fell to $38, but by year's end
would be back at $42. In late 1968 three private Swiss banks agreed to buy
$200-400 million worth of gold from South Africa, selling this gold on the
market.[7] The South Africans were unwilling to deal with
their traditional agents the Bank of England, reportedly because the Bank's
close relationship with the Fed would compromise the secrecy of South Africa
's sales.
With price
still far above $35 in October 1968 and South Africa able to sell some of
their gold, the monetary boycott was an all out failure. Henry Fowler decided
to offer South Africa a compromise. He would allow the South Africans to
resume monetary gold sales, but only to the IMF, not central banks.
Furthermore, sales could only be made when the market price of gold was below
$35 or South Africa was experiencing a capital account deficit.
This plan would
set a floor for the gold price at $35. Since all South African gold would
flow to the IMF once price fell below $35, the market would no longer be
absorbing this rather considerable lode of metal, and price would stabilize.
As they were still running a capital account surplus and the price of gold
remained high, confident South African officials ignored the offer.
The Boycott
Succeeds
Around the
world, the bull market in equities that had begun in 1966 was ending as
markets began a downwards spiral into the 1969-70 bear market. South Africa,
once attractive to investors, began to lose its shine. By the second quarter
of 1969, South Africa 's capital account revealed a deficit, its first in
three years. Net inflows of private capital amounted to a paltry £11.7
million for the first half of 1969, down from £218 million the year
prior.[8]
The pillar that
had been allowing South Africa to avoid open market gold sales had cracked.
To fund imports, South Africa began to sell its gold in earnest. Reserves,
which had hit a peak of $1.4 billion at the end of May 1969, fell to $1.2
billion by July[9] and $1.1 billion by August.[10] The gold price in London fell from $43.50 to $41.
According to estimates, all new South African gold production, about 20
tonnes a week, was now hitting the market.[11]
The sell off
turned into a bloodbath in late October. Prices broke below $40. Through
November gold continued to plummet, falling into the $35 range at the end of
the month. On January 16, 1970 prices touched $34.80, the lowest level since
the London gold market had reopened in 1954.
At prices
significantly below $35, it made sense for central banks to arbitrage gold,
but no longer by drawing on US reserves. Rather, banks could buy in London at
$34.80, ship the gold to the US for 10¢, and have the Fed issue dollars
for gold at $35, after taking a 7.5¢ commission. This promised a sure
2.5¢ per ounce profit. The effect was that the US was now accumulating
reserves. The tables had turned, and Fowler's plan had worked. The $35 peg
seemed to have been saved, though at the expense of freedoms lost by everyone
caught up in the endeavour.
Aftermath
With gold at
$35, in December 1969 South Africa agreed to the US compromise offered more
than a year before. Its freedom to sell monetary gold was still drastically
limited — it could still only sell to the IMF, and at prices below $35
— but this was better than nothing, and at least a floor had been set
below the gold price.
Newspapers and
magazines were filled with fawning accounts of the US's victory. A January
op-ed in the New York Times noted that: "Gold's power to disrupt
the international monetary mechanism has now been greatly reduced, and
possibly ended. Under Secretary of the Treasury Paul A. Volcker has voiced
the hope that this latest move will dispose of gold as a 'contentious
monetary problem'."[12]
This
celebration would be short-lived. Even with South Africa selling most of its
gold in London, the gold price steadily rose through 1970, ending the year at
$37.50. By August 1971 it would be trading in the free market at $43.50,
again 20% above the official price. In spring of 1971 a run on the US dollar
began. Central banks lined up at the Fed's doors in ever increasing numbers
to demand their gold. On August 9, the British economic representative asked
to convert an astonishing $3 billion into gold, or about 2,500 tons.[13] The South Africa gamble had been the last trick up
the US's sleeve, and on August 15, 1971 President Nixon officially abandoned
the dollar's $35 peg when he ended convertibility of dollars into gold.
Comparing
1968-69 to present day
The 1968-69
South African gold embargo is not just an interesting historical quirk. It
also provides a mirror to understand the means by which governments will
combat the present failure of the financial system. Like the $35 gold and
Bretton Woods, much of the world's financial architecture has been designed
by government technocrats. Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and their foreign
equivalents like the Canadian Mortgage and Housing Corporation dominate much
of the home lending markets. The Federal Reserve and other central banks
control the supply and quality of money, and agencies like the SEC, Fed, and
OFHEO have monopolies on regulation.
This
architecture is crumbling. In a free market, housing lenders and banks who
fail at their task are taken over by more able competitors. Private
regulators who do a poor job as watchdogs have their reputations crushed, to
be succeeded by regulators who better understand their domain. Charities that
bail out those who don't deserve help will lose funding at the expense of charities
that better target aid. In this way failed architecture is renewed.
Much like the
US's decision to save Bretton woods by coercing South African gold sales,
today's governments will resort to ever more authoritarian measures rather
than allowing their pet institutions to fail. Already the legislation
governing central banks has vastly expanded in scope, federal housing
agencies have had their mandates dramatically increased, and government
regulators who fell asleep at the wheel are being given ever greater powers.
While this may
work temporarily, much like South Africa's forced sales saved the $35 peg for
one more year, the financial architecture's endemic problems will still
exist. Instead of being purged, they will only crop up further down the road,
more serious than ever. And when this happens you can be sure our elected
officials will again try to save their pet institutions by taking away our
liberties.
Notes
[1] The Economist, January 6,
1968.
[2] New York Times, January 4,
1969.
[3] New York Times, July 13,
1969.
[4] Time, July 25 1969.
[5] New York Times, June 16,
1968.
[6] New York Times, Jun 28, 1968.
[7] New York Times, Jul 26, 1969.
[8] The Economist, Aug 30, 1969.
[9] New York Times , July 13,
1969.
[10] New York Times, Aug 15, 1969.
[11] The Economist, Nov 22, 1969.
[12] New York Times, Jan 5, 1970.
[13] Peter Bernstein, The Power of Gold. Pg. 351.
John Paul
Koning
John Paul
Koning is a financial writer and graphic designer who runs Financial Graph & Art.
His Recent History of Gold, 1954-2009 Wallchart is available here.
|