|
(This item originally appeared in Forbes.com on
January 19, 2012.)
http://www.forbes.com/sites/nathanlewis/2012/01/19/what-is-stable-value-in-currency-terms/
The reason that we use gold, in a gold standard system, instead of, say,
orange juice, is because we are trying to accomplish a goal, and gold is the
best way to do so. Our goal is to create a currency of stable value.
“Why do you use titanium to build a nuclear submarine?” one could
ask. “Why not copper? Or ‘pork bellies’? Isn’t it
completely arbitrary? A mere superstition?” These people always think
they are very sophisticated.
I can then imagine a prim Russian submarine engineer patiently explaining, to the imbecile he is faced with, that the
submarine isn’t going to work if you make it out of bacon.
Today I want to talk more about this notion of “stable value.” I
talked about this before, but it is an important point. We all understand
instinctively what it means. We all use money every day. However, it is a
little more difficult when you try to explain this in words.
People often confuse “stable value” with “stable purchasing
power.” This has been going on for centuries. David Ricardo said in
1817:
It has been my endeavor carefully to distinguish
between a low value of money and a high value of corn, or any other commodity
with which money may be compared. These have been generally considered as
meaning the same thing; but it is evident that when corn rises from five to
ten shillings a bushel, it may be owing either to a fall in the value of
money or to a rise in the value of corn …
The effects resulting from a high price of corn when produced by the rise in
the value of corn, and when caused by a fall in the value of money, are
totally different.
Here’s a similar passage from Ludwig Von Mises, dating from 1949:
Changes in the purchasing power of money, i.e., in
the exchange ratio between money and vendible goods and commodities, can
originate either from the side of money or from the side of the vendible
goods and commodities. The change in the data which provokes them can occur
either in the demand for and supply of money or in the demand for and supply
of the other goods and services.
First, I think we have to recognize something: that money has a value. For
example, the value of the dollar, in terms of euros, is determined exactly in
the foreign exchange market. We can see the value of the dollar going up and
down there, at least in relative terms, compared to the euro. The dollar is a
floating currency; of course it goes up and down in value.
The dollars in our pockets (base money) are exactly the same as the dollars
being traded in the forex market (also base money).
Otherwise, there would be arbitrage opportunities. For some reason, we are
encouraged to think of these as two separate universes, but that is not true
at all. So, we should think of these dollars in our pockets as going up and
down in value, every day and indeed every minute, even though the price of a
Happy Meal doesn’t change that quickly.
The dollar is a floating currency. It is going up and down in value. The euro
is also a floating currency. It is also going up and down in value. So,
comparing one moving target with another moving target is confusing at best.
I want you to form a concept of the dollar going up and down in value also in
“absolute terms.” We measure everything else in absolute terms,
as absolute as we can manage. When we say that something is exactly 467
millimeters long, that has an exact meaning –
and exact length. The dollar has an absolute value, which is of course going
up and down.
Unfortunately, we really don’t have any concrete standard for this
notion of “absolute value,” that we can measure with scientific
precision. However, we can observe the effects of changes in value, the forms
of monetary distortion that correspond to a rise in currency value and a decline
in currency value. So, this is not imaginary. The effects of a change in
monetary value are very concrete.
Over centuries of experience, people have discovered that gold is the single
best approximation of this “standard of absolute value,” the one
thing in the world whose value is most stable. Not only is it better than
other options, it is so close to the ideal that no great problems arise.
Thus, it is the best thing in the world to use when you want to make a
monetary system whose goal is the most stable currency value possible, just
as titanium is what you want to use when you make nuclear submarines.
I won’t try to defend that assertion here. But let me ask you this:
let’s say your goal is to make the most stable currency possible. But,
you can’t use gold, as a reserve asset or even as an indicator or
benchmark. How would you do it?
Just think about that for a while. Many people have, over hundreds of years.
I suppose someone will argue that some sort of consumer price index or
commodity basket would work. That would mean the “price” (ratio
between the currency and the commodity basket) would be exactly the same. The
CRB continuous commodity index, to take one example, would have a value of
100 for ten or a hundred years at a stretch. Is that what you want? Would you
allow changes in the index components or weightings? How would those changes
be decided? What if there is a general rise in the real value of commodities,
as has often happened during wartime for example?
How would it work from day to day? Would you have some sort of redeemability system? An automatic currency board type
system? Or would the CPI or commodity basket just serve as an indicator for
some kind of board of “wise men” such as today’s FOMC? In
that case, would they use some sort of interest-rate target system as is in
use today? Is there any country that has used such a system (yes: Brazil)?
Has such a system ever been tested? What if it doesn’t work the way you
think it does?
Send me your best ideas. I want to hear them. It is extremely unlikely that
you would come up with anything that wasn’t investigated and dismissed
a century ago. If you were such a monetary genius as to devise a system
significantly better than a gold standard, for achieving the goal of stable monetary
value – something thus far unique in human experience — we would
already be personal friends. But give it a try, if you want to.
You will eventually see why a gold standard system is the best way to achieve
this goal. We know this because we have centuries of experience. I mentioned
before the record of British government bond yields during the gold standard
era – a record which is not only the best in all of recorded history,
untouchable by today’s central banks, but it is so close to perfection
that it is silly to try to improve upon it.
You could make a submarine out of steel. It might work, but it wouldn’t
be as good as a titanium one. You could make a submarine out of aluminum, and
it still might work, and it still wouldn’t be as good. You could make a
submarine out of pure copper – a soft metal – and it would sink.
Creativity is fun, for a little while, and then you have to get down to
business.
In 1900, after two hundred years of direct experience with
the gold standard system, British people were completely satisfied
that it accomplished their goal of maintaining a stable currency value. After
two hundred years of experience, do you think they could have been mistaken
about that?
It was only when their goals changed – when they wanted a currency that
was manipulable for various policy goals – that Britain decided to adopt other systems.
Today, we are still fascinated by the idea of manipulable
currencies. This is not the first time in history that this has happened. It
has been very common. However, the most successful countries have always been
those that adopted a policy of stable money, rather than manipulated money.
The reason for this is simple: it is a lot easier and more effective to do
business that way. Productivity improves. People become wealthier. It’s
no more complicated than that.
Nathan Lewis
|
|