While Carl Menger
and Léon Walras simultaneously discovered
the principle of marginal utility, their ideas about the nature of market
prices are very different. Walras was more
interested in the final equilibrium prices arrived at by traders than the
process by which these prices were formed. Therefore, he dramatically
simplified the pricing process by imagining it as if it were governed by an
auction mechanism capable of instantly calculating all prices in an economy.
For his part, Menger
was fascinated with the actual process by which prices are formed. Rather
than trying to abstract from the messy process of haggling by devising an
artificial auction mechanism, Menger worked with a
number of real-life pricing scenarios including isolated bargaining, monopoly,
and competitive exchange.
As a result of these different
approaches, prices in a Walrasian universe have
different characteristics from prices in a Mengerian
universe. Rather than registering at a single determinate equilibrium price,
as is the case with Walrasian prices, Mengerian prices tend to be dispersed within an
indeterminate range. In financial markets, we call this range the bid-ask
spread.
Perhaps the best way to illustrate
these two thinkers' differences on price is to use as our example the
modern-day phenomenon of high-frequency traders (HFTs) and the digital tracks
they leave as they operate in electronic equity markets.
High-Frequency
Trading
High-frequency trading is the use
of computer algorithms to guide trading decisions in securities markets. HFTs
will hold securities for no longer than a few seconds, and for as little as
microseconds. It is estimated that they now account for anywhere from
50–70 percent of all equity trades in North America.
Nanex charts
Nanex, a market data firm, provides a number of
hauntingly strange charts showing the behavior of HFTs operating on the
microsecond level. We provide a few of these charts below.
Figure 1
his first chart
represents price data for the ETF iShares S&P
Target Date 2020 Index Fund (TZG). These quotes were submitted to the NYSE Arca exchange in a ten-second period just prior to the
9:30 a.m. market opening of September 23, 2010.
As in most securities markets,
prices in equity markets are described by way of "bids" and
"offers". The price at which a buyer is willing to purchase an equity is submitted to the relevant exchange as a bid. [1] In
the chart above, the bid price is represented by the lower line. A number of
bid orders may build up, with the "best bid" being the highest of
the submitted bids. On the offer side, the price at which a seller is willing
to offload an equity is submitted to the exchange as
an offer. In the TZG chart above, this is the top line. Out of all submitted
offers, the "best ask" (or "best offer") is the lowest
one.
Between the "best bid"
and "best ask" lies an empty channel called the bid-ask spread. In
the chart of TZG, the bid-ask spread is the difference between the "best
bid" in green and the "best offer" in red. This is a
no-man's-land in which no market actor is, for the time being at least,
willing to transact.
What is remarkable about the chart
above is the steady cycling of the pattern of bids and offers and the
microscopic space of time over which they occur. This is no human-created
pattern, for no trader could submit this many quotes this fast, nor could
they do so in such a remarkably consistent pattern. This is a pattern created
by trading algorithms.
Or take this pattern:
Figure 2
The price quotes submitted to
NASDAQ in the above chart — which represents a fraction of a second
(11:44:55) — shows a rapidly repeating pattern of changing bid prices
between $20.77 and $20.80 in the PowerShares DWA
Technical Leaders Portfolio ETF (PDP). Note that the ask price, represented
by the top line, remains constant, and that the bid price represented is not
the best bid, but some price below the best bid. The rate at which the bid
price is changing is far too fast for human comprehension. This is an HFT at
work.
Or check out the algorithm action
on Blackstone Group (BX) on September 15, 2010:
Figure 3
This chart
represents three seconds of cycling bid and ask quotations
submitted to the BATS exchange by an HFT, or group of HFTs.
There are a number of other charts
at Nanex's website including the fascinating but
very complicated one below. [2] See
if you can figure out what is going on. Suffice it to say, battling
algorithms on a number of different exchanges are competing to provide offer
prices for Casey's General Store (CASY) over a period of around one second.
Figure 4
Competing algorithms manipulating
the bid-ask spread on equity exchanges perfectly illustrates a thoroughly Mengerian idea: that of Preiskampf,
or "price duel."
In determining how prices are
formed in such duels, Menger imagines isolated
individuals coming together in a bargaining process. [3] He
begins by considering a grain producer and a wine producer. The grain
producer is prepared to exchange at most 100 units of his grain for 40 units
of wine, and would be especially happy if he could give less units of grain
for a unit of wine, say 99 units of grain for 40 units of wine. The wine
producer is prepared to exchange 40 units of her wine for only 80 units of
grain, and would be happy to receive more units of grain for the wine, say 81
units of grain for 40 units of wine. Neither side knows the other's strategy
and price-marks. But if a trade is to occur, it will happen somewhere between
the 80 units of grain the wine producer is willing to accept and the 100
units the grain producer is willing to pay.
At which exact price will the
transaction occur? This depends on each producer's relative talents in
bargaining. The wine producer will begin by submitting her first offer
— say 110 units of grain. The grain producer will submit his best bid
for the wine — say 70 units. The size of the bid-ask spread in the wine
market is therefore 40 units of grain. Neither is willing to transact at
these prices, so they will begin to bargain, slowly narrowing the bid-ask
spread. The wine producer reduces her offer from 110 to 100, while the grain
producer raises his from 70 to 80. The spread is now just 20 units (80 to
100), and both the price offered by the wine producer and the price bid by
the grain producer are sufficient for the other side to transact. The grain
producer may immediately consummate the trade at 100 units of grain for the wine,
or the wine producer may be more eager and accept the price of 80 units of
grain for her wine.
But if both sides in the price war
think they can extract a bit more from the other, then the bargaining will
continue. Like the HFTs in the charts above, they will try and read each
other's intentions so as to determine their respective desperation or lack
thereof, and with this information update their bargaining strategy. Says Menger,
Each of them will direct his
efforts to turning as large a share as possible of the economic gain to
himself. The result is the phenomenon which, in ordinary life, we call bargaining.
Each of the two bargainers will attempt to acquire as large a portion as
possible of the economic gain that can be derived from the exploitation of
the exchange opportunity, and even if he were to try to obtain but a fair
share of the gain, he will be inclined to demand higher prices the less he
knows of the economic condition of the other bargainer and the less he knows
the extreme limit to which the other is prepared to go. (Menger,
Principles of
Economics, p. 195)
The location in the bid-ask spread
at which the trade is consummated depends
upon their various individualities
and upon their greater or smaller knowledge of business life and, in each
case, of the situation of the other bargainer … there is no reason for
assuming that one or the other of the two bargainers will have an
overwhelming economic talent … therefore, I venture to state, as a
general rule, that the efforts of the two bargainers to obtain the maximum
possible gain will be mutually paralyzing. (p. 195–196)
Now let's bring this back to the
HFTs in Nanex's charts. The odd patterns exhibited
by trading algorithms are little more than graphical representations of Mengerian price duels. In these duels, the final price at
which stock is transacted depends on each algorithm's respective talent and
the "greater or smaller knowledge" of all duelers involved. Bidding
algorithms may make quick feints up into the spread by issuing a sudden
stream of new bid quotes, either hoping to goad other buying algorithms into
following them, or to instigate algorithms on the sell side to respond.
Algorithms providing offer quotes hope to do the same by making quick plunges
down into the spread. These submitted quotations are meant to provide false
information to other algorithms so as to confuse them, or to gather
information from reacting algorithms so as to take advantage of them. By
gleaning tidbits about their competitors, or providing them with false
knowledge, algorithms and those who deploy them hope to gain for themselves a
favorable spot in the bid-ask spread. [4]
And Walras
In imagining the structure in which
transactions are facilitated, Walras begins from a
different starting point than Menger. Whereas Menger begins with bilateral exchange among isolated
individuals and then worked through monopoly and competitive exchange, Walras begins with a fully formed and centralized auction
market:
The markets which are best
organized from the competitive standpoint are those in which purchase and
sales are made by auction, through the instrumentality of stockbrokers,
commercial brokers or criers acting as agents who centralize transactions in
such a way that the terms of every exchange are openly announced and an
opportunity is given to sellers to lower their prices and to buyers to raise
their bids. (Walras, Elements of
Pure Economics, p. 84)
Walras's centralized
market is coordinated by an all-knowing auctioneer. Prior to the market
opening for trade, the auctioneer cries out at random the price ratios of
various goods and all participants in the market place submit to the
auctioneer the quantities they will demand at that price. If there is an
imbalance between supply and demand for stocks at the announced prices, the
auctioneer will quickly adjust prices until the demand and supplies of all
stocks in the market balance. The auctioneer then informs each individual the
prices at which they will transact, and with whom. The market opens and trade
occurs. It then closes again for the next auction.
Walras's auctioneer
precludes the sort of market phenomena that Menger
found so interesting. In particular, in a Walrasian
market there are no bid-ask spreads, and therefore
no reason for HFTs and their warring algorithms to exist.
Spreads arise, in part, because HFTs and other market actors do not know
when or if they will be able to resell a stock — after all, there is no
auctioneer who guarantees a sale come the next market period. Therefore, the
spread represents the price that must be paid to a buyer or seller to
compensate them for enduring the possibility of future illiquidity. Knowing
that an auctioneer will always facilitate a future trade means that there is
no threat of illiquidity, and therefore no reason to demand a spread so as to
compensate.
Spreads also arise because market
actors have different levels of knowledge about the securities being traded.
The less informed therefore demand a price spread to compensate them for
enduring the possibility of unintentionally buying bad securities from savvy
traders, or selling good ones to them. In a Walrasian
setup, the auctioneer informs all participants about the nature of goods
available on the market. This levels the informational playing field and
precludes any motivation for the emergence of a spread.
While infinite liquidity and
information remove the psychological motivations for the emergence of
a spread, the Walrasian setup also physically
prevents the emergence of spreads. Because an auctioneer monopolizes the
price-setting process by soliciting the amounts demanded from all actors at
various prices prior to the market opening for trade, HFTs are effectively
barred from fiddling themselves with various bid and offer prices so as to
get valuable information prior to exchange. Secondly, all final prices and
quantities are given to actors by the auctioneer. Because every trader is
literally forced to accept the same price when the market opens, no HFT can
transact in a way so as to obtain a better price. The market machinery, so to
say, is out of HFT's hands in a Walrasian setup.
Conclusion
In a Walrasian
market, HFTs simply have nothing to do. Walrasian
prices don't hover in an indeterminate range bounded by bids and offers, as
they do in a Mengerian market, but are singular and
given. There is no reason for price duels, because the auctioneer removes
both the psychological motivation for their emergence and the physical
capacity for any sort of spread to arise. In short, Walrasian
pricing can't explain the wondrous patterns that Nanex
has isolated, but Mengerian pricing can.
Notes
[1]
There are
dozens of equity exchanges in the United States. Traders submit bids and
offers for a given equity to whichever exchange they desire. The exchanges
consolidate these quotes into the "consolidated tape" — the
combined range of bids and offers over all exchanges for a given equity. The
"best bid" and "best offer" is that bid or offer that is
the best across all exchanges. The more prevalent exchanges (and their Nanex codes) include the NASDAQ (NSDQ), the BATS Exchange
(BATS), the Boston Stock Exchange or NASDAQ OMX BX (BOST), Direct Edge
(EDGE), and the Pacific Exchange or NYSE ARCA (PACF).
[2]
"Crop Circle of the Day," Nanex.
[3]
The example
begins on page 177 of Principles of
Economics.
[4]
According to Hülsmann, Mises: Last Knight of Liberalism (2007), Menger's early experience as a journalist writing market
surveys at the Wiener Zeitung, a government controlled newspaper that
reported on business and stock markets, influenced the content of the Principles of Economics. No wonder Menger's thought applies so well to modern stock markets.
|