Texte de mon
allocution lors de l'American dream coalition annual conference à
Seattle, le 18 Avril 2009 (en fait, j'ai dû raccourcir un peu en
séance, mais l'idée est là...)
-------------
LAND
USE REGULATIONS,
Housing
unaffordability and other socially undesirable impacts in France
First, I would like to thank the American Dream
Coalition for this invitation (…)
I’m
here because two years ago, I released for a French Think Tank, the Turgot
Institute, a full study reviewing the housing public policies in France. As
the study was deeply appreciated, it became a book.
One of
the purposes of the study was to understand why we experienced such an
unprecedented housing bubble. When the study was ordered, we thought that our
study would mainly emphasize monetary phenomenon, or issues relative to
credit practices, just like the one which exist in the USA. We expected that
land use regulations would be one factor among others. It appeared to be, by
far, the main factor explaining our bubble.
CAUSES OF THE REAL
ESTATE BUBBLE IN FRANCE
Did we
have a real estate Bubble in France, like in some parts of the USA ? The
answer is obviously: Yes. The median multiple (using net disposable income)
of real estate deals on the territory began to diverge from its historical
mean of 2.9 (which was observed, within a 10% fluctuation range, between 1965
and 2000), at the beginning of the new millennium, and reached a whopping
range of 4.6 to 5.0 in 2007, according to various sources (The following
graph uses ratios relative to gross disposable income so figures are a bit
lower, from 2.5 to 4.2) .
Gross median multiple
ratio – 1936 to 2008
source ADEF
This bubble was especially remarkable because it was the first time it
reached such intensity, but also because for the first time, it was not an
“urban bubble” or a “Paris Bubble”. Prices of
existing or new homes peaked in the same proportions either in central metro
areas or in rural cities as far as 30 miles from these metro areas. They
peaked in many metro areas with 50 000 inhabitants and more, not only in very
big dense areas like Paris or Lyon or Azure Coast.
This
graph shows that house prices increased 90% faster than households’
revenues between 1997 and 2007. In non inflation-adjusted prices, it
corresponds to a whopping 140% gross increase.
index
of median home prices / median net household revenue, 1965 = 1
Source: ADEF
Most publications explain this only by an increase in demand favoured by low credit
rates. Of course, this explanation is half true, since average fixed rates to
households were divided by a two fold between 1997 and 2005 (from 8.6 to
4.3%). This fall of credit rates allowed borrowers to lengthen the maturity
of their loans, and, at equal revenue, a typical household could borrow about
50 to 70% more than it could before. Many analysts stop their reasoning here.
“That’s demand, period”.
Every
good economist should react to this by saying that if the supply was not
constrained, an increase in household’s solvability would result in an
increase of housing supply, since early signals of price hike would bring
newcomers on the market. Especially, housing market has very low barriers to
entry, isn’t prone to the formation of monopolies… This
didn’t happen. We can see that, despite price increase begun in 1999,
the supply began to soar only in 2004, and remained far under historical
records (553 000 homes in 1973).
Supply didn't
follow demand
between 1999 and
2004
Source:
Bulle-immobiliere.org
How can we be sure that most part of the housing bubble comes from land use
regulations?
First,
if the gross price of homes and flats grew by 140% in the ten years of the
bubble, construction costs only grew by 30% in the same time.
Orange
and green curves: condo and house prices
purple curve:
construction costs
Source:
Bulle-immobiliere.org
It’s about 10% more than inflation. It can’t explain a 100% price
hike on every home, new or ancient. Construction costs grew at a much slower
rate than CPI between 1965 and 1997, the current trend inversion comes mainly
from some regulatory strengthening in public housing, and some workforce
shortages in some particular housing jobs. Not something really relevant
compared to the global price increase.
But
when I studied the share of land into the price of new homes, I discovered
that raw developable land prices increased 6 times in the same period, though
the costs of technical land development (sewage, electricity and other
networks, roads and so on) only grew in the same proportions than
construction costs. In fact, in most areas, land prices were the same in
Euros in 2007, than they were in our good old Francs in 1997 (1€ # 6.5
Francs). On coastal areas, the prices increased from 10 to 12 times. Only in
some very isolated and economically very depressed rural areas, we
didn’t see such prices increases.
Agricultural
land didn’t follow the same trend. Even at more than 15 miles from big
metro areas’ fringes, developable land is as much as 200 times more
expensive than agricultural one. At the fringe of big cities, the
factor can jump up to 500 or 1000 times.
The
latest point that convinced me that we were experiencing a “land
oriented bubble”, was the discovery that in most housing programs with
multiple lots, small lots were sold at much higher rates, in Euros per square
meters, than bigger one. This shows the presence of a “regulatory penalty”,
as first described by US economists Glaeser and Gyourko. This penalty
corresponds to the price of a theoretical zero square foot lot on an
operation.
We don’t have, in France, national databases with free access that
could have allowed me to compute precisely this regulatory penalty. But some
examples coming from real operations show that this penalty, in rural towns
neighbouring (20-30 km) big cities, could represent about one third of the
total cost of the home in 2006, much more than in 1998 or 2000. And,
sometimes, it may be more.
Do we
have a tough land use regulation in France?
The
answer is, once again, yes.
The
current frame of our regulation comes from a 1967 law, which allowed cities
to promulgate zoning plans. That doesn’t say that there was nothing
before: there were rules that “protected”, i.e. prevented from
being built, agricultural land. But the 67 law marked the beginning of the
application of zoning laws in France.
You will say: how a regulation promoted in 1967 could produce some real
estate price frenzy only since 1997 ? This argument is often raised by people
who don’t want to hear about the responsibility of zoning laws in real
estate bubbles. The answers are multiple.
First,
general economic theory reminds us that you must have high demand and a
constrained supply to get prices becoming mad. The two conditions were not
met together until the late nineties. Inflation, and thus interest rates, was
high in the late 60s, in the 70s and during the 80s, when central banks
decided that inflation had to come back under control. High interest rates
didn’t allow too long lending times, so the maximum prices people could
afford for homes wasn’t so high. In the beginning of the nineties, most
western economies (USA, UK, France, Germany, Sweden…) were slightly
depressed, and the real interest rates (the difference between gross rates
and CPI rates) remained high.
You
need both factors to get a bubble started: high demand fuelled by low credit
rates, and tough development regulations. Interest rates determine how much
you CAN pay for your home, but regulations strength determines how much you
WILL pay, somewhere within the range between zero and what you can pay.
Second
point, the focus of the land use regulations shifted from early times to now.
In the first times of their applications, so called “sprawl”
wasn’t a great issue out of the circles of professional planners. So
the regulatory tools to prevent sprawl were there but the elected councils
weren’t eager to use them too much. Zoning plans were used to try
to separate housing activities from other ones. So the first plans that were
made in the 70s didn’t really limit or restrict access to developable
land. And most of the smaller cities didn’t make zoning plans, because
it wasn’t mandatory.
Let’s
add that the 60s and 70s were, in France, the golden age of public housing
constructions, generally with regulatory “exemptions” from the
1967 common law... As the dominant ideology was that state had to do
something to provide dwellings to low wage families, it made it on a wide
scale (state was not heavily in debt in those times).
Let’s
come back to our regulatory zoning purposes.
In the
late 80s, we began to see a shift into the purpose of regulatory zoning.
Environmentalist movements became to sue cities councils whose zoning plans
didn’t address environmental issues enough, from their perspective.
They were greatly helped by additions of successive layers of European and
National laws over the 1967 framework. The new layers reinforced the obligation
to preserve natural and agricultural land from being built. Coastal laws, Wet
zone laws, biodiversity laws, natural zones preservation laws… In the
same time, environmentalists were successful to push “sprawl” as
the ultimate evil in many politicians’ minds. So zoning plans became
progressively anti-sprawl plans, too.
All
this stuff came mostly during the 90s and turned the regulatory process
of building a new zoning plan into a real mess.
In the
USA, Glaeser and Gyourko showed that the crucial variable that explained most
of the bubble in the USA was the necessary time to build homes from scratch,
on a raw land. When you put a long bureaucratic regulatory step for the sole
purpose of making a raw land authorized for building, you’re likely to
push up prices when demand soars.
In
France, the necessary time to shift from an old zoning plan to a new one,
when the old one didn’t fit any more the current needs of the city, was
estimated to about 18-24 months in the 80s. Now, three years is the minimal
time frame to put these new plans to birth. But if some environmentalist
associations put the city’s project into litigation, the process can
last much longer. I saw some small cities struggling in 7 years of judicial
battles, just to add +- 50 acres of new developable land into their plan. For
example, it took 6 years to the 20 cities of the metro area of Nantes (# 800
000 inhabitants, ranking #10 in France) between the beginning and the end of
the elaboration of their latest plan, brought to life in late 2007.
Of
course, for some limited purposes, the law provides some “quick
change” possibilities. But even with those tools, you have to spend at
least 6 months to put very small amounts of land into the building market.
And even for those limited development openings, you can face judicial
procedures, so a one year time frame for small changes is closer to reality.
So the
process of building a new zoning plan is such a hassle that new cities’
councils don’t want to engage too often into it. Once per election cycle
is the great maximum, and a plan must last at least 10 to 15 years. So you
have to forecast in advance the amount of land you will have to use to meet
the housing needs of your population.
The
plans that came into applications in the early 2000s were built during the
mid 90s: at this time, the rhythm of new construction was driven by high
interest rates, and nobody could forecast a big drop in interest rates. So
many councils didn’t put enough land with immediate availability in
their plans, and if some of them put some land for “future”
availability, with “quick change” processes available, it was
generally not enough to follow the huge increase in demand driven by credit
rates. So the price of land started to soar from 1998 to 2007.
CONSEQUENCES OF THE
REAL ESTATE BUBBLE
Estimation
of the planning penalty In France:
I used
the same “rough edged” calculation formula than Randall O’
Toole used to determine the planning penalty paid by US house purchasers to sellers
in his “planning penalty” report released for the ADC and the
Cato Institute a few years ago. For the year 2005, the house price index,
relative to the households’ revenues, reached a value of 170. If you
assume conservatively that values within the range of 90-110 are
historically normal, that 10 additional points could be attributed to a
slight increase in building costs, and that historical prices doesn’t
include any share of planning penalty, it leaves us with 50 points on
170, about 30% of the total, that can be attributed to the planning
regulations.
There
were about 800 000 housing deals concluded during this year, at a median
price of 192 000 Euros (# 215 000$ Purchasing Power Parity Adjusted at this
time). If our land use regulations have been closer to the one existing in
Dallas or Houston, every French household purchasing a home could have saved
57 000 Euros or 64 000$. The total sum transferred from purchasers to sellers
in 2005 was about 46 Bn Euros, i.e. 2,7% of our GDP.
Who
are the “winners” and the “losers” of the planning
penalty?
People
generally feel richer when their homes see their market value increasing. But
are they really? People who sell an overpriced home win nothing if they have
to buy an overpriced home in the same time. Except that transaction fees and
taxes are generally calculated from this overpriced tax base… The first
purchasers are clearly the losers in this situation. On the opposite, people
who own several houses and who can sell them just to reduce their real estate
inventory are neat winners. So are landowners whose land has been promoted
from “non developable” to “developable” and thus sold
it at a good price to developers. Though no statistic corroborates this view,
it’s not exaggerated to say that the group of home purchasers is, in
average, less wealthy than the group of home sellers.
So the
planning penalty transferred in 2005 about 2.7 % of our GDP from a less
wealthy set of population to a wealthier one. Not exactly what one calls
“fairness”...
46 Bn
Euros are 9 times more than the money that France devotes to the minimal
social revenue for the poorer families, or twice the amount of subsidies
devoted to public and private housing.
Anti-sprawl
laws generate “rural sprawl”
The
law of unintended consequences strikes again through the observation of the
effect of anti-sprawl laws on population growth. Here’s a map of the
country surrounding the city of Nantes, but I could have Chosen Montpellier,
Rennes, Lyon or many others to illustrate my point.
The
darker the circle, the faster the relative growth
Near Nantes : small
rural towns are growing faster...
Source : Comittee for
Loire-Atlantique's economic Development
On
this map of the Nante's region, The two biggest yellow zones are Nantes
and Saint-Nazaire metro Areas. Nantes and its region experienced a neat
positive migration flux from people coming from more expensive places, mostly
from Paris.
As you
can see, Nantes and Saint nazaire grew, but slowlier than the department's
average. But now, see the number of red and brown circles surrounding Nantes.
Most of these cities are small, from 1000 to 15 000 inhabitants. They grew up
to 45% in just 7 years during the bubble.
Though
these small cities experienced the same land price hike (# 6 times in 10
years) than bigger ones closer to Nantes, they remained the only place where
middle wage families could afford a lot to build a home.
But
such small cities were not prepared to see their population growing so fast.
Despite a widening of their tax base, they can’t face the induced
expenses in new schools, new school bus lines, new swimming pools and sport
facilities… Remember that in France, many of these amenities are nearly
exclusively provided by the public sector.
So
some housing programs in these small cities have just become rural
dormitory-cities. Roads leading to big urban Areas like Nantes or
Saint-Nazaire (#150 000 inhabitants) are overly congested and have sometimes
badly deteriorated, since neither structures nor crossings were originally
made for the traffic levels we’re experiencing today. Anti-sprawl laws,
by making more difficult to find affordable homes in the boundaries of big
metro areas or at their immediate fringes, created anarchic development in
rural areas which were not able to bear such unprecedented growth.
Corruption
of political life
For
the first time, the 2006 activity report of our central agency for corruption
prevention noticed that urban zoning laws and land use regulations were
becoming a major source of concern, as the difference between farmland and
land for housing grew.
Of
course, the phenomenon can’t be quantified, but officials refer to it
as “not any more anecdotal”.
Other
Environmental effects
Zoning
law didn’t prevent our urban landscapes from being messed up by big
“soviet like” buildings, generally erected in the frame of big
public housing programs from the 50s to the 70s, which obtained special
derogatory rights because of their “social purpose”.
One of the mass
public housing program built in the 60-70s
And these are not
the ugliest you can find...
More
interestingly, it looks like beautiful landscapes’ preservation tends
to be endangered when the land is under the threat of being too severely
protected by the zoning laws. One example : great wildfires generally occur
from beautiful woods that could be classified as “natural reserve”,
or anything approaching. Most of them are considered as arsons.
Why is there a
political demand for such zoning laws? Who makes a living from zoning
laws?
People
tend to love freedom for themselves but fear freedom for others, because
“others” could make a bad use of this freedom. Zoning laws are
the political answer to this demand. People well connected use the
“democratic process” to maximize freedom to use their own land
according their own goals, when the land use plan is elaborated. Then they try
to limit this ability for others, either because of inherent NIMBYism of
human nature, or in order to maximize the gain they can get from these
regulations.
This
demand is addressed first by local elected, who generally see in zoning laws
a good way to protect their own interests, and, eventually, to harm their
local opponents. Second, a huge bureaucracy emerged either in big cities, or
ingovernment agencies, under the pretext of “expertise”, which
must absolutely legally be associated to the democratic process of elaborating
plans, or is in charge to enforce them.
Since
the 80s, when European laws made more difficult for French state to do things
that can be normally made by private contractors, the bureaucracy which
“made” plans just turned into a bureaucracy which “supervises”
the private consulting firms which are paid to elaborate plans. So there is a
huge and influential private sector taking advantage of state made zoning
laws, which is efficiently lobbying to extend them. Crony capitalism is
always the best ally of socialism.
How
many people are involved in this heavily state generated business? It’s
impossible to figure it out exactly. My very own rough calculations comes to
a very conservative estimate of at least 30 000 people (full time adjusted)
under public job contracts, living from zoning. And it doesn’t include
private contractors, full time or occasionally working for zoning purposes.
Things
becoming worse: towards new urban disasters ?
This
lobby is far more efficient than the very few economists who dare to examine
the role of land us regulations in the economy. Even if some politicians
start admitting, very smoothly, that there is a regulatory problem with our
land use regulations, they remain inaudible. There is absolutely no doubt, in
the view of the two main political parties in France, that sprawl is evil,
and must be fought. And the recent carbon dioxide Frenzy has led to the
creation of new regulatory powers which carefully tend to impose
their own anti sprawl views to cities, even if cities would like to
deregulate, or even simply relax regulations aimed at limiting sprawl.
Until
the end of the 90s, even if big cities were bound under tough regulations to
elaborate their plans, at least they were under competition to create the
most entertaining places to attract people. This could lead some peripheral
suburbs to adopt less severe restricted policies, which at least provided
some oxygen to home builders.
This
ability is disappearing through an insidious process, namely
“intercommunality”. For instance, the 22 cities of the metro area
of my living town of Nantes have been “strongly convinced” to
elaborate “joined plans”, under an exhaustive “coherent
sustainable development scheme”. What’s the result? There are
still about 17 300 hectares (#40 000 acres) of farm land at the fringe of
Nantes Metro Area. The sustainable development plan imposes that this amount
shall never go under 17 000. So, at least for the next 15 years, there are
only 300 ha (#750 acres) of new farmland available for new buildings. So few
for a nearly 1 million people metro area! Metropolitan areas like
Rennes even decided to impose a green urban boundary around them. Prices in
Rennes have been Skyrocketing during the bubble years.
Many metro
areas across the country are currently adopting such mandatory
“sustainable development schemes” (In French, "SCOT",
Schéma de Cohérence Territoriale").
New
buildings will only be made on brownfields, or on existing homes, in the
frame of publicly driven operations of “urban renewal”. The
current motto of planners is: “we have to rebuild the city over the
city”. It sounds beautiful, but will surely turn many of our cities
into new urban disasters.
The
Austrian Economist Friedrich Hayek famously stated that no planners, no
experts, can handle all the criteria that every individual decision requires.
Even worse for planners, they can’t evaluate how subjective valuations
of every individual criterion can change with time.
So
they tend to give importance only to the criteria that are important to them,
and to the politicians they’re advising. In the 50s and 60s, they
focused mostly on the quantitative need for new dwellings, so they created
dehumanised soviet-like suburbs which today are concentrating all the
problems of poverty and frustration of our society. They created more than
700 so called “urban ghettos”, urban disasters with awfully
degraded dwellings, lack of basic equipments like libraries, high schools,
and so on… The spiritual children of these early planners now say us
that they will reinvent the town. They promise us new “ecopolis”
just as our elders were told about “radiant cities”. It's time to
be afraid !
Planners
tell us that leaving free market forces at work on land use matters would
lead to anarchy and environmental disasters. But, seriously: When private
developers fail so miserably, they tend to do it once. Perhaps twice or three
times, because sometimes several competing bad projects are brought to
markets simultaneously. But never has any business driven under undistorted
market laws generated more than 700 failures ! And nobody says we should let
build anything without some environmental requirements. But environmental
concern must not become a pretext to prevent anything from being built.
As
Hayek said, market acts as a “decentralized planner”: private
developers are careful to bring to the market developments that market wants.
So they have to take in account what’s existing. So called
“market anarchy” is only the expression of the impossibility to
valuate how individual preferences will change over time. Price system is the
way people make compromises between what they would like to have in an ideal
world, and what they can afford according to their revenues. Markets are the
best tools to make these millions of individual adjustments possible.
Conclusion
Another
consequence of the current planning frenzy, and this will be my conclusion,
is that as soon as economy will recover – and if none knows when it
happens, it will happen – and therefore demand for houses will soar
again, then, we will know another housing bubble, and another housing bubble
crisis, with all its disastrous social issues.
Knowing
all we now know about the deadly economic, political, environmental and
social effects of zoning regulations, we should take the opportunity of
currently falling prices to scrap down all these regulations, because house
owners won’t be as much concerned by the loss of value of their homes,
since it’s happening all the same. We should enact land regulations
that let owners decide what to do with their land.
But
I'm not that optimistic: planning forces are too powerful, it won't happen.
Thank
you for your attention
French
Savvy readers can read more articles on french
housing policies and economics of housing market here.
Vincent
Bénard
Objectif Liberte.fr
Egalement par Vincent Bénard
Vincent Bénard, ingénieur
et auteur, est Président de l’institut Hayek (Bruxelles, www.fahayek.org) et Senior Fellow de Turgot (Paris, www.turgot.org), deux thinks tanks francophones
dédiés à la diffusion de la pensée
libérale. Spécialiste d'aménagement du territoire, Il
est l'auteur d'une analyse iconoclaste des politiques du logement en France, "Logement,
crise publique, remèdes privés", ouvrage publié
fin 2007 et qui conserve toute son acuité (amazon), où il
montre que non seulement l'état déverse des milliards sur le
logement en pure perte, mais que de mauvais choix publics sont directement
à l'origine de la crise. Au pays de l'état tout puissant, il
ose proposer des remèdes fondés sur les mécanismes de
marché pour y remédier.
Il est l'auteur du blog "Objectif
Liberté" www.objectifliberte.fr
Publications :
"Logement: crise publique,
remèdes privés", dec 2007, Editions Romillat
Avec Pierre de la Coste : "Hyper-république,
bâtir l'administration en réseau autour du citoyen", 2003, La
doc française, avec Pierre de la Coste
Publié avec
l’aimable autorisation de Vincent Bénard – Tous droits
réservés par Vincent Bénard.
|