Despite the celebrations among Democrats, yesterday a majority of
Supreme Court justices ruled that the Constitution does not allow the
government to force Americans to buy health insurance. However in providing
the swing vote to uphold the Affordable Care Act (aka Obamacare)
Chief Justice John Roberts broke with the four other justices who shared that
view by declaring that the methods chosen to get individuals to buy insurance
were not penalties but taxes. He declared that the government wasn't legislating behavior, but simply taxing it. In reaching
this tortured decision he erred by declaring the penalties to be taxes and
then compounded the mistake by classifying them as "indirect taxes"
that are not imposed on individuals. Apparently Roberts feels that these two
wrongs will make a right. But his mistake will cost this country dearly.
The Obama administration admits that because the law makes it illegal
for insurance companies to discriminate based on pre-existing conditions it
eliminates the incentive for healthy people to buy insurance. Any rational
healthy person would simply forego expensive insurance until they were old
enough or sick enough to actually need it. Since insurance companies need the
money they make from healthy people to compensate for the money they lose
from sick people, the plan would collapse if the government did not devise a
mandate that would convince or compel all individuals to buy insurance.
In selling the plan to the public, President Obama repeatedly claimed
that these burdens were penalties, not taxes. In addition to the stated
intent of the lawmakers, the standard legal definitions that separate taxes
from penalties make it clear that the new financial burdens are penalties,
not taxes. A tax is an exaction to raise revenue. If its primary purpose is
to compel behavior then it is considered a penalty.
But Roberts argued that since the "tax" on not buying is
lower than the actual cost of insurance, then the penalty will not force
anyone to buy. He did not specify a level at which the "tax" would
become determinative thereby becoming an unconstitutional penalty. However,
since Congress can raise the tax anytime it wants, the mechanism is already
in place for it to do exactly what the Supreme Court ruled it can't. Does
Roberts expect to review the case every time Congress raises the penalty? The
fact that Roberts feels that the penalty is ineffective is irrelevant. It is
not the Court's job to judge the efficacy of legislation, just its
constitutionality.
Robert's conclusion that the Federal government can't require that
people buy health insurance but can impose a tax on those who don't is a
distinction without a difference. After all, if the tax was high enough,
individuals would have no choice but to comply. It has been clearly
established that Congress can't do with the tax code what it lacks the
constitutional authority to do with legislation. That is why the Constitution
had to be amended in order to ban the sale of alcohol. Prohibition would have
been much easier to achieve by simply raising alcohol taxes sufficiently to
eliminate its sale. But such a tax would have been unconstitutional. The same
principal applies to health insurance. Congress can't simply use taxes to
force Americans to buy health insurance.
Even if you buy Robert's logic that the penalty is a tax, he still
should have ruled it unconstitutional because all direct taxes, except income
taxes as described by the 16th Amendment, must be apportioned. The
government's power to tax is not absolute. Taxes fall into two classes,
direct and indirect, and there are specific rules for each. Alcohol and tobacco
taxes are indirect taxes, and are subject to the rule of uniformity. You only
pay them if you buy the products, and you do so indirectly through the
merchants who sell them. If you do not buy the products you pay nothing.
However, the only way to avoid paying the tax for not buying health
insurance is to buy a product that you do not want. So either way you pay.
And since the taxpayer pays the tax directly to the government, it's a direct
tax, which must be apportioned by state according to each state's percentage
of the nation's total population.
Roberts allowed the government to free itself from this straightjacket
by redefining the meaning of a direct tax. He asserted that the tax for not
buying health insurance is indirect because it affects not all Americans but
only those who fail to buy health insurance and who have sufficient income to
pay. But the percentage of people who are subject to a tax has nothing to do
with the class to which it belongs. The 19th Century income tax was declared
unconstitutional because it was an unapportioned
direct tax. The fact that less than 2% of the population was initially
subject to it was beside the point.
As with Prohibition, to impose an unapportioned direct income taxes on individuals
the government had to pass the 16th Amendment to the Constitution. It should
have to do it again for a direct tax on those who fail to buy health
insurance.
The Supreme Court has ruled (incorrectly in my opinion) that estate
and gift taxes fall into the category of indirect taxes, even though they are
paid directly to the government. The court ruled that these are not direct
taxes on individuals, but excise taxes levied on the privilege of giving
gifts or bequeathing property. They could try to apply the same twisted logic
to health insurance, but it would be quite a stretch to classify the right
not to buy health insurance as a privilege.
In the final analysis, since the court ruled that the government
cannot force Americans to buy health insurance, and that the stated purpose
of the Affordable Care Act is to do precisely that, it is clearly
unconstitutional, regardless of the legal trickery the court used to declare
otherwise.
If the government had tried to slip an unconstitutional penalty by the
Court by disguising it as a tax, then Obama may have been on the wrong end of
yesterday's decision. Instead he chose a losing argument but Roberts found a
loophole to uphold it anyway. Despite his stated preference for restraint,
this is the ultimate in judicial activism. This awful ruling makes it more
evident that the ballot box provides the only remedy for freedom loving
Americans.
I offer more on this
topic in my latest video blog.
|